Showing posts with label salerno. Show all posts
Showing posts with label salerno. Show all posts

Sunday, November 23, 2008

Consumer Deflation: The New Fashion

``All the major institutions in the world trying to deleverage. And we want them to deleverage, but they’re trying to deleverage at the same time. Well, if huge institutions are trying to deleverage, you need someone in the world that’s willing to leverage up. And there’s no one that can leverage up except the United States government.-Warren Buffett, Interview Transcript

This world is full of befuddling ironies.

Just last year, when consumer prices were rampaging skywards, we were told by media and their experts how “inflation” was bad for the economy. Today, as consumer prices has been falling, the same forces of wisdom explain to us how “deflation” has likewise been detrimental to the economy or perhaps even worst….

As example we are told that declining consumer prices “aren’t just symptom of economic weakness” but are “destructive in and of themselves”. Why? Because as demand weakens and prices decline, companies cut employment and investment, slowing economic growth even further. Thus the chain of inference includes “falling earnings, a weak economy, and the hoarding of cash, fewer investors are willing to buy stocks during deflationary times.”

And the “deflation” theme has grabbed the headlines see figure 1.

Figure 1: Economist: The Deflation Index

According to the Economist, ``Back in August, only six stories in the Wall Street Journal, International Herald Tribune and the Times mentioned “deflation”. In November, there have already been 50, and new figures released this week will mean many more. America's consumer-price index fell by 1% in October from September as oil prices plunged, the largest monthly fall since the series began in 1947. Britain's inflation rate has also fallen from its record high of 5.2% in September to 4.5% in October, the biggest drop in 16 years.

For starters, falling prices basically reflect demand supply imbalance, where supply is greater than demand. Such conditions may be further prompted by either supply growing FASTER than demand or demand declining FASTER than supply.

Paradox of Savings And Growth Deflation

When prices fall because of technological innovation such as the mobile phones, the internet and others, these items become affordable and have rapidly been suffused into the society enough to make it an economic staple.

For instance, mobile phones are expected to hit an astounding 61% global penetration level according to the UN (Europe News) or about 6 out of 10 people will have access or be using mobile phones by this year. According to high profile economist Jeffrey Sachs, the diffusion of mobile communications will revolutionize logistics and education that should benefit the rural economy.

Quoting Mr. Sachs, ``The mobile revolution is creating a logistics revolution in farm-to-retail marketing. Farmers and food retailers can connect directly through mobile phones and distribution hubs, enabling farmers to sell their crops at higher “farm-gate” prices and without delay, while buyers can move those crops to markets with minimum spoilage and lower prices for final consumers.

``The strengthening of the value chain not only raises farmers’ incomes, but also empowers crop diversification and farm upgrading more generally. Similarly, world-leading software firms are bringing information technology jobs, including business process outsourcing, right into the villages through digital networks.

``Education will be similarly transformed. Throughout the world, schools at all levels will go global, joining together in worldwide digital education networks. Children in the US will learn about Africa, China, and India not only from books and videos, but also through direct links across classrooms in different parts of the world. Students will share ideas through live chats, shared curricula, joint projects, and videos, photos, and text sent over the digital network.” (underscore mine)

Moreover, falling prices should translate to more purchasing power.

So how can falling prices be all that bad?

The answer lies squarely on the Keynesian dogma of the “Paradox of Savings”. What supposedly signifies as virtue for individuals is allegedly (and curiously) a bane for the society. The idea is that when people save or withhold consumption, the underlying consequence would be a reduction in investments, employment, wages, etc. etc, thereby leading to a slowdown or even a contraction of economic growth. Seen from the aggregate top-down framework, less consumption equals less economic growth.

This has been profusely peddled by media and the social liberal school as basis for justifying GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION to conduct policies aimed at stimulating growth or rescue, bailout or other inflationary policies to avoid “demand contraction”.

Anecdotally, if savings is truly so bad for an economy then Japan should be an economic basket case by now, yet it holds some $15 trillion in household assets as of June, of which only 13.9% is in stocks and mutual fund and $7 trillion in bank deposits. This in contrast to the US where only 17% is in deposits and 50% is into stocks and pension funds (Washington Post). Japan’s high savings rate has even been reflected in public sentiment where a polled majority refuses to accept government offers to “stimulate” the economy (see Free Lunch Isn’t For Everyone, Ask Japan), as it had learned from its boom-bust cycle experience.

From the Austrian school perspective, the Japanese scenario can be construed as a “Cash Building Deflation” case. From Mises.org’s Austrian Taxation of Deflation by Joseph Salerno, ``Despite the reduction in total dollar income, however, the deflationary process caused by cash building is also benign and productive of greater economic welfare. It is initiated by the voluntary and utility-enhancing choices of some money holders to refrain from exchanging titles to their money assets on the market in the same quantities as they had previously. However, with the supply of dollars fixed, the only way in which this increased demand to hold money can be satisfied is for each dollar to become more valuable, so that the total purchasing power represented by the existing supply of money increases. This is precisely what price deflation accomplishes: an increase in aggregate monetary wealth or the “real” supply of money in order to satisfy those who desire additional cash balances.”

In addition, this Keynesian obsession with “aggregate demand” says economic growth should be associated with “inflation”.

Figure 2: American Institute For Economic Research: Falling US Dollar

Yet, if inflation is measured by means of the increase or loss of a currency’s purchasing power, then the US dollar’s appalling loss of purchasing power since the birth of the Federal Reserve in 1913 (see figure 2) shows that US economic growth hasn’t been primarily driven by productivity (productive economy=an environment of falling prices or “deflation” as more goods or services are introduced) but by inflationary policies or by money and credit expansion!

Note: the chart also exhibits that when the US dollar had been redeemable into monetary commodities (gold or silver), purchasing power of the US dollar tends to increase. Yes, this is defined as DEFLATIONARY ECONOMIC GROWTH or GROWTH DEFLATION (!)

Again from Mises.org’s Austrian Taxation of Deflation by Joseph Salerno, ``In fact, historically, the natural tendency in the industrial market economy under a commodity money such as gold has been for general prices to persistently decline as ongoing capital accumulation and advances in industrial techniques led to a continual expansion in the supplies of goods. Thus throughout the nineteenth century and up until the First World War, a mild deflationary trend prevailed in the industrialized nations as rapid growth in the supplies of goods outpaced the gradual growth in the money supply that occurred under the classical gold standard.” (highlight mine)

Falling Markets: Debt Deflation Not Consumer Price Deflation

But savings isn’t about the absolute withholding of consumption. There is a very significant time dimension difference: it is a choice between spending and consuming today or in the future. Moreover, there are two types of consumption to reckon with; non productive consumption and productive consumption.

The definition of savings according to the Austrian School, excerpting Gerard Jackson, (underscore mine)``The full definition is that savings is a process by which present goods are transformed into future goods, i.e., capital goods, that produce a greater flow of consumer goods at some further point in time. In short, present goods in the form of money are used to direct resources from consumption (the production of consumer goods) into the production of capital goods.”

When we put cash balances into a bank, the bank functioning as intermediary parlays such deposits into loans (for business or for consumers) or as investments in securities (private e.g. corporate bonds or public-local government e.g. municipal bonds or national government e.g. Treasuries). So essentially, our savings are channeled into the private sector or as financing to government expenditures.

Thus, the paradox of savings or the anticipated rise of savings rate in the US or in countries severely impacted by the deflating mortagage backed credit bubble, given the magnitude of government efforts to “cushion” or “rescue” the financial system and the economy, will effectively be utilized to finance most of these government programmes.

The negative aspect is not that the consumption ripple effect will result to lower economic growth but instead savings channeled into public/government consumption effectively crowds out private investments which should lead to LOWER productivity and thereby lower economic growth prospects.

Furthermore, when media discusses about consumption, it focuses on the consumers which accounts as the non-productive aspect of consumption.

A productive consumption is where one consumes in order to be able to produce goods. A baker who consumes food in order to bake is an example of productive consumption.

And non-productive consumption, as defined by Dr. Frank Shostak, is ``when money is created "out of thin air." Such money gives rise to consumption, which is not backed by any production. It leads to an exchange of nothing for something.”

In short, the recent boom in consumer spending hasn’t been on the account of spending for production but representative of an explosion of “nothing for something” dynamics or where a policy induced free money environment impelled the US populace to go into a massive speculative orgy, thereby giving the illusion of wealth from producing nothing and limitless nonproductive consumer spending. Of course many of these nothing for something dynamics has also spilled over to many developed countries.

Likewise, the recent account of falling prices or economic weakness hasn’t been a direct cause of retrenching consumers but as an offshoot to a reversal in the free money landscape and a bursting bubble. Thus the apparent economic weakness from a slackening of consumer spending signifies as symptom and not the cause.

Put differently, what makes falling prices or what media or the Keynesian perception of pernicious deflation is nothing more than DEBT DEFLATION!

Once more from Joseph Salerno’s Austrian Taxation of Deflation [p.13-14], ``The most familiar is a decline in the supply of money that results from a collapse or contraction of fractional-reserve banks that are called upon by their depositors en masse to redeem their notes and demand deposits in cash during financial crises. Before World War Two bank runs generally were associated with the onset of recessions and were mainly responsible for the deflation that almost always characterized these recessions. What is called “bank credit deflation” typically came about when depositors lost confidence that banks were able to continue redeeming the titles—represented by bank notes, checking and savings deposit —to the property they had entrusted to the banks for safekeeping and which the banks were contractually obliged to redeem upon demand…

``During financial crises, bank runs caused many banks to fail completely and their notes and deposits to be revealed for what they essentially were: worthless titles to nonexistent property. In the case of other banks, the threat that their depositors would demand cash payment en bloc was sufficient reason to induce them to reduce their lending operations and build up their ratio of reserves to note and deposit liabilities in order to stave off failure. These two factors together resulted in a large contraction of the money supply and, given a constant demand for money, a concomitant increase in the value of money.”

As you can see Salerno’s description of a Debt Deflation landscape as “depositors lost confidence that banks were able to continue redeeming the titles”, “revealed for what they essentially were: worthless titles to nonexistent property”, “threat that their depositors would demand cash payment en bloc”, anda large contraction of the money supply and, given a constant demand for money, a concomitant increase in the value of money” have been all consistent and cogent with today’s evolving activities in the banking system, the global financial markets or the real economy.

As we have pointed out in many past articles as the Demystifying the US Dollar’s Vitality or It’s a Banking Meltdown More Than A Stock Market Collapse!, the collapse in the US mortgage market which accounted for as a major source of collateral for an alphabet soup of highly geared structured finance (e.g. ABS, MBS, CMBS, CMO, CDO, CBO, and CLO) instruments which likewise underpinned the $10 trillion shadow banking system, resulted to a near cardiac arrest in the US banking system last October, where banks refused to lend to each other reflecting symptoms of an institutional bank run (see Has The Global Banking Stress Been a Manifestation of Declining Confidence In The Paper Money System?).

The sudden surge or “increase in the value of money” in terms of the US dollar against the an almost entire swathe global currencies (except the Japanese Yen) reflected its role as international currency reserve where its dysfunctional banking system incited a systematic “hoarding” of the US dollar, the unwinding of the US dollar carry trade or almost a near contraction of money supply (until the US government’s swift response see The US Mortgage Crisis Taxpayer Tab: $4.28 TRILLION and counting…).

Similarly such dislocations have been transmitted via synchronous selling and an astounding surge in volatility across global financial markets and an intense disruption in the $14 trillion trade finance market, all of which has combined to impact the global real economy.

The present selloffs in the global equity markets as reflected by the activities in the US markets have reached milestone levels see Figure 3.

Figure 3: chartoftheday.com: US Stock Market Corrections

The meltdown in the US markets have been on short, in terms of duration, but whose magnitude has been more than the average of the typical bear market losses.

Why should it be that a selldown be remarkably drastic if it were to account for only a consumer recession? The answer is it isn’t.

Thus, the so-called destructiveness isn’t about US consumers retrenching but an intense deleveraging process backed by the heuristic reflexivity concept of a self-feeding loop of falling prices=falling demand and vice versa.

Eventually false premises tend to be corrected.


Will Debt Deflation Lead To A Deflationary Environment?

``Let's get to the bottom line. A deleveraging process is under way. It can happen against a background of bankruptcy, deflation, declining cash flows and bank bankruptcy or in a slower way against a background of inflation. Both reduce the debt burden, but one is socially jarring and led in the past to mass unemployment and arguably WWII. Democracies will choose the inflationary approach. This is not evident today, but it will be more evident soon enough as the BoJ, ECB, BoE and others realise that their current monetary policy is driving them not to slower growth and lower inflation but to deflationary calamity. Today, you can see the calamity of the deflationary disease but what will you see tomorrow, or the day after, if the monetary cure pours from the medicine jars of the global central banks?”-Russell Napier of CLSA (courtesy of fullermoney.com)

Not if you ask, Dr. Frank Shostak, ``We however, maintain that it is not the size of the debt that determines the severity of a recession, but rather the aggressiveness of the loose monetary policies of the central bank. It is loose monetary policies of the central bank that cause the misallocation of resources and the depletion of the pool of funding and in turn can be manifested in over-indebtedness. So to put the blame on the size of the debt as the key factor in causing depression is no different to blaming the thermometer for causing the high temperature.” (underscore mine)

Or Joseph Salerno in Austrian Taxation of Deflation, ``Bank credit deflation represents just such a benign and purgative market adjustment process.”

Many have cited the Great Depression as a prospective model of today’s deteriorating environment as having a deflationary character. Yet, the reason debt deflation transformed into the Great depression wasn’t due to the deleveraging process itself, instead it was debt deflation aggravated by economic policies which crushed profit incentives.

Again Mr. Salerno (highlight mine), ``Unfortunately such benign episodes of property retrieval have been forgotten in the wake of the Great Depression. Despite the fact that the bank credit deflation that occurred from 1929 to 1933 was roughly proportional in its impact on the nominal money supply to that of 1839-1843, the rigidity of prices and wage rates induced by the “stabilization” policies of the Hoover and early Roosevelt Administrations prevented the deflationary adjustment process from operating to effect the reallocation of resources demanded by property owners.”

Myths of Liquidity Trap and Pushing On A String

Deflation proponents have further used the Keynesian concepts of “liquidity trap” and or “pushing on a string” to advance their Armageddon theory.

The concept of “pushing on a string” suggests that US Federal Reserve policies will be rendered ineffective or impotent and won’t jumpstart the economy by stimulating lending.

While the US Federal Reserve have the boundless powers to add into bank reserves by purchasing assets (usually government liabilities), commercial banks might not lend money to take advantage of this. It’s like leading a horse to a pool of water, but doing so won’t guarantee that the horse will drink from it.

A liquidity trap environment is seen almost similar to the “pushing on a string” concept, but here, as interest rates nears or is at the zero regime, traditional policy tools might also be unsuccessful to spur lending (again!).

So should we fear these as media and Keynesian experts paint them to be?

We doubt so.

Why?

First is to understand how Central banks operate, according to Murray Rothbard in Man Economy and State (emphasis mine), ``The central bank can increase the reserves of a country’s banks in three ways: (a) by simply lending them reserves; (b) by pur­chasing their assets, thereby adding directly to the banks’ deposit accounts with the central bank; or (c) by purchasing the I.O.U.’s of the public, which will then deposit the drafts on the central bank in the various banks that serve the public directly, thereby enabling them to use the credits on the central bank to add to their own reserves. The second process is known as discounting; the latter as open market purchase. A lapse in discounts as the loans mature will lower reserves, as will open market sales.

Next, Murray Rothbard in Making Economic Sense tells us why deflation isn’t likely to occur given the innumerable powers of Central Banks, ``What deflationists always overlook is that, even in the unlikely event that banks could not stimulate further loans, they can always use their reserves to purchase securities, and thereby push money out into the economy. The key is whether or not the banks pile up excess reserves, failing to expand credit up to the limit allowed by legal reserves. The crucial point is that never have the banks done so, in 1990 or at any other time, apart from the single exception of the 1930s. (The difference was that not only were we in a severe depression in the 1930s, but that interest rates had been driven down to near zero, so that the banks were virtually losing nothing by not expanding credit up to their maximum limit.) The conclusion must be that the Fed pushes with a stick, not a string.”

Figure 4: Dshort.com: US Monthly Inflation Chart

A dainty chart from dshort.com shows of the historical bouts of deflation in US history. Most of the incidences of deflation came on a post war basis after a massive expansion in money supply and artificial demand from a war economy resulted to massive adjustments during in the post war economy.

Since the gold has come off the monetary standard in 1971, despite the strings of crisis during the period (Savings and Loans, Black Monday 1987, LTCM, & dot.com bust), there has been no incidence of deflation.

The Nuclear Option: Currency Devaluation

Another, US Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke in 2001 spelled out his unorthodox “helicopter” means of avoiding a deflationary recession.

The Fed has always the luxury to use its printing presses, this from Mr. Bernanke’s speech Deflation: Making Sure “It” Doesn’t Happen Here, ``To stimulate aggregate spending when short-term interest rates have reached zero, the Fed must expand the scale of its asset purchases or, possibly, expand the menu of assets that it buys. Alternatively, the Fed could find other ways of injecting money into the system--for example, by making low-interest-rate loans to banks or cooperating with the fiscal authorities. Each method of adding money to the economy has advantages and drawbacks, both technical and economic. One important concern in practice is that calibrating the economic effects of nonstandard means of injecting money may be difficult, given our relative lack of experience with such policies. Thus, as I have stressed already, prevention of deflation remains preferable to having to cure it. If we do fall into deflation, however, we can take comfort that the logic of the printing press example must assert itself, and sufficient injections of money will ultimately always reverse a deflation.”

Or even consider massive devaluation as its nuclear option (emphasis mine), ``Although a policy of intervening to affect the exchange value of the dollar is nowhere on the horizon today, it's worth noting that there have been times when exchange rate policy has been an effective weapon against deflation. A striking example from U.S. history is Franklin Roosevelt's 40 percent devaluation of the dollar against gold in 1933-34, enforced by a program of gold purchases and domestic money creation. The devaluation and the rapid increase in money supply it permitted ended the U.S. deflation remarkably quickly. Indeed, consumer price inflation in the United States, year on year, went from -10.3 percent in 1932 to -5.1 percent in 1933 to 3.4 percent in 1934. The economy grew strongly, and by the way, 1934 was one of the best years of the century for the stock market. If nothing else, the episode illustrates that monetary actions can have powerful effects on the economy, even when the nominal interest rate is at or near zero, as was the case at the time of Roosevelt's devaluation.”

About fifty years ago, in his magnum opus the Human Action, Mr. Ludwig von Mises presciently elucidated of the endgame option available to central banks wishing to escape a credit bubble bust, ``The wavelike movement affecting the economic system, the recurrence of periods of boom which are followed by periods of depression, is the unavoidable outcome of the attempts, repeated again and again, to lower the gross market rate of interest by means of credit expansion. There is no means of avoiding the final collapse of a boom brought about by credit expansion. The alternative is only whether the crisis should come sooner as the result of a voluntary abandonment of further credit expansion, or later as a final and total catastrophe of the currency system involved.” Our Mises moment.

In short, a government single-mindedly determined to inflate the system won’t actually need a functioning private credit system to do so. As we previously said, it only needs the bureaucracy and 24/7 operational printing presses, or it can simply invoke massive devaluation as its nuclear option.

Proof?

Zimbabwe should be the best living testament of such government driven tenacity.

From Albert Makochekanwa, Department of Economics, University of Pretoria, South Africa “Zimbabwe’s Hyperinflation Money Demand Model

``Borrowing from Keynes (1920) suggestions, namely that ‘even the weakest government can enforce inflation when it can enforce nothing else’; evidence indicates that Zimbabwean government has been good at using the money machine print. Coorey et al (2007:8) point out that ‘Accelerating inflation in Zimbabwe has been fueled by high rates of money growth reflecting rising fiscal and quasi-fiscal deficits’. As a result of that, the very high inflationary trend that the country has been experiencing in the recent years is a direct result of, among other factors, massive money printing to finance government expenditures and government deficits. For instance, the unbudgeted government expenditure of 1997 (to pay the war veterans gratuities); the publicly condemned and unjustifiable Zimbabwe’s intervention in the Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC)’s war in 1998; the expenses of the controversial land reform (beginning 2000), the parliamentary (2000/2005) and presidential (2002) elections, introduction of senators in 2005 (at least 66 posts) as part of ‘widening the think tank base’ and the international payments obligations, especially since 2004, all resulted in massive money printing by the government. Above these highlighted and topical expenditure issues, the printing machines has also been the government’s ‘Messiah’ for such expenses as civil servants’ salaries.”

As you can see, no consumer or industrial or any sorts of borrowing-spending Keynesian framework. It's plain vanilla print and distribute, where money supply exponentially outgrows the supply of goods and services, hence hyperinflation.

So even as US government policy tools have seemingly been unsuccessful to stoke up on its much desired rekindling of the inflationary environment after coughing up about $4.28 trillion of taxpayers money (see The US Mortgage Crisis Taxpayer Tab: $4.28 TRILLION and counting…), to quote Asha Banglore of Northern Trust, ``The lowering of the Federal funds rate, the Fed’s innovative programs to provide liquidity to financial institutions – PDCF, TSLF, and other programs – and more lenient rules for borrowing through the discount window appear to have exhausted the gamut of possibilities routed through monetary policy changes to influence aggregate demand. The provisions of the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008 allow for recapitalization of banks. The FDIC is working on obtaining an approval for the anti-foreclosure plan to address the housing market issues that are central to the current crisis. In conclusion, the probability of a hefty fiscal stimulus package with the Fed buying these securities is growing everyday,” the nuclear option or our Mises Moment endgame seem likely a looming reality as the day goes by.

Conclusion: Preparing For The Mises Moment

Finally, as shown above deflationary fears under a Paper money standard seems unwarranted and is not a likely scenario, given the unrestricted powers of the central bank to either use the printing press or its nuclear option- massive debasement of its currency.

Debt deflation in itself is a salutary process which involves the cleansing of malinvestments or the excesses of “exchange of nothing for something” dynamics.

The Great Depression was a product not of debt deflation dynamics only, but was exacerbated by the adaptation of rigid economic policies by the incumbent leadership that crushed business profits and the economic system’s ability to adjust.

Governments determined to inflate don’t need a functioning private banking or credit system as the Zimbabwe experience shows. All it needs is a printing press and an expanding bureaucracy.

Once the inflation process starts to gain ground be prepare for the next bout of inflation!