Showing posts with label real savings. Show all posts
Showing posts with label real savings. Show all posts

Sunday, August 02, 2020

The Historic Gold and Bond Bull-Market Tango


Under the Gold Standard, or any other metallic standard, the value of money is not really derived from gold. The fact is, that the necessity of redeeming the money they issue in gold, places upon the issuers a discipline which forces them to control the quantity of money in an appropriate manner; I think it is quite as legitimate to say that under a gold standard it is the demand of gold for monetary purposes which determines that value of gold, as the common belief that the value which gold has in other uses determines the value of money. The gold standard is the only method we have yet found to place a discipline on government, and government will behave reasonably only if it is forced to do so--Friedrich A. Hayek 

The Historic Gold and Bond Bull-Market Tango 

Remember my outlook on Gold last February? 

What you are about to see is a defining monumental process in financial history!  

Lo and Behold, Gold’s phenomenal rise against central banking’s Fiat Money standard! 

Aside from all other (fiat) currencies, gold prices broke to record highs this week against the last holdover, the USD.  

Oh, Gold!!!! February 23, 2020  
 
From the US perspective, record USD gold prices have been attained as USTs hit record low yields amidst a flattening curve. Furthermore, gold prices have surged along with a resurgent buildup of global negative-yielding bonds, even as personal savings rate hit record highs.  

There are those who want to excoriate Nobel Laureate Milton Friedman for saying that inflation was everywhere and always a monetary phenomenon. But he also proposed the Permanent Income Hypothesis. The Permanent Income Hypothesis, according to the Wikipedia, supposes that a person's consumption at a point in time is determined not just by their current income but also by their expected income in future years—their "permanent income". In its simplest form, the hypothesis states that changes in permanent income, rather than changes in temporary income, are what drive the changes in a consumer's consumption patterns. Its predictions of consumption smoothing, where people spread out transitory changes in income over time, depart from the traditional Keynesian emphasis on the marginal propensity to consume. It has had a profound effect on the study of consumer behavior, and provides an explanation for some of the failures of Keynesian demand management techniques. 

Though the monetary mechanism is necessary for inflation to occur, it is insufficient. Other real factors are material to its existence. 

The surge in personal savings appears to reinforce Friedman’s PIH theory.   

The deflationary impact of a recession must be remedied by an increase in savings.  

Wrote the dean of the Austrian school Murray N. Rothbard*,  

Furthermore, deflation will hasten adjustment in yet another way: for the accounting error of inflation is here reversed, and businessmen will think their losses are more, and profits less, than they really are. Hence, they will save more than they would have with correct accounting, and the increased saving will speed adjustment by supplying some of the needed deficiency of savings. 

*C. Secondary Developments of the Business CycleMan, Economy, and State, with Power and Market 

Even in the Philippines, the same process is in motion. This excerpt showcases how businesses are likely to react to the disruptions caused by work stoppage policies to contain the virus. 

From Philstar (August 2): Enterprises hit by the pandemic may have to pause operations temporarily once their cash flow turns negative and consider other opportunities in agriculture and digital space, Presidential Adviser on Entrepreneurship and Go Negosyo founder Joey Concepcion said. “My advice to many of our MSMEs (micro, small and medium enterprises) and I always share this with them: You have to have a plan. You have to remain cash flow positive and if you turn cash flow negative, at a certain point in time, don’t wait until it depletes your entire working capital or even your family’s savings.” “Close the business for the time being because it’s not going to be worth wasting all your family’s savings and it will create more problems for you. That’s my advice to many of our entrepreneurs,” he said in an interview on the The Chiefs aired on One News.” This counsel goes against the mainstream ivory tower based ludicrous prescription that one should take advantage of low rates and borrow to spend. 

Furthermore, based on the analysis of sectoral balances, fiscal deficit equates to net private saving or private sector surplus. So the financing of the US record deficit would translate to massive increases in domestic and or foreign private savings. 

That buildup of savings appears to be consistent with the recent spike in deficits. 

However, the US isn’t the only nation experiencing unprecedented deficits. Most of the world have ramped up public spending such that McKinsey and the IMF expect the global deficit to reach a historic $11 trillion in 2020! That’s about 12% of the $90 trillion global GDP. 
So if sopping up of savings wouldn’t be sufficient, global central banks are likely to be filling in the vacuum through debt monetization. Global debt hit a record of $258 trillion or 331% of the Global GDP in the 1Q. But debt issuance picked up speed in the 2Q, according to the Reuters, "Overall gross debt issuance hit an “eye-watering” record of $12.5 trillion in the second quarter, compared with a quarterly average of $5.5 trillion in 2019, the IIF said. It noted that 60% of those issues came from governments". 

Nevertheless, the current amount of money printing may be inadequate to offset structural deflationary forces embedded in the system, such as excessive debt, overcapacity in several significant sectors, and zombie financing, as well as, recent policies used to constrict the spread of the pandemic.   

For instance, even after the $2.2 trillion bailout package called the Cares Act and the $3 trillion expansion of the Federal Reserve’s assets, the US GDP suffered a 9.5% YoY (32.9% quarter annualized)! But their stock markets rocketed instead. 

For a broader purview of the economic damage caused by recent policies to contain Covid-19:  Singapore suffered a 41.2% contraction quarter on quarter and 12.6% year on year. Hong Kong shrank by 9% YoY. The Euro-zone area declined by 12.1% YoY while the US suffered a 9.5% YoY (32.9% quarter annualized) even after the $2.2 trillion Cares Act and the $3 trillion expansion of the Federal Reserve’s assetsChina escaped a recession by posting a positive 3.2%. 

As an aside, the Philippines will be reporting its 2Q GDP on August 6th. Based on the PSA’s data on Gross Regional Domestic Product, the NCR and CALABARZON area contributes about 52% of the total statistical economy (2018).  Along with the rest of Luzon, during the ECQ or MECQ period, economic activities were mostly suspended within these areas.  And strict quarantine policies were also implemented in parts of Visaya and the Mindanao region.  If only 30% of the capacity of the CALABARZON and NCR had been in operations in 2Q, not counting other parts of the nation, how much loss of output will these translate to?    

Lastly, inflation is not set on the stone by Federal Reserve asset purchases or QE as exhibited by the immediate post World War II era. Though monetary actions matter, again, many other factors will determine inflation’s appearance.   
 
As the Eurodollar wiz Alhambra Partner’s Jeffrey Snider wrote of the Fed’s inflationary panic episodes post-World War II:  

Like the 1947-48 bond buying episode (the Fed’s inflation panic), we’re supposed to believe that the central bank played the pivotal role in keeping the financial situation orderly, trading off that priority by risking an inflationary breakout. Bullshit. That’s the myth that has been conjured, hardly in keeping with the reality of the situation. 

Sure, the Fed monetized the bills during WWII, but so what? The depressionary conditions rampant throughout the markets and economy led the private system to easily monetize everything else, the vast majority. Even the Fed’s inflation panic in bond buying was a tiny drop in the bucket. 

Yields said so. 

Furthermore, record money supply’s transmission into street inflation represents a time-consuming complex process that will have to confront opposing forces that may offset its impact. And there will be action-reaction feedback loops that contribute to the process.   For instance, if money creation adds to the money supply, debt defaults subtract to it. 

That is, should global central banks succeed in the re-combusting of inflation, this would only happen when inflationary monetary forces overwhelm deflationary structures, which would take time. 

As I concluded last February, 

Whether street inflation surges or not, in reaction to the massive supply-side disruptions from a crucible of real adverse forces in the face of central bank actions, the escalating uncharted experiments on monetary inflation have pointed to the magnification of uncertainty on a global scale. 

The bottom line: Gold's uprising against central banking fiat currencies warn that the world is in the transition of entering the eye of the financial-economic hurricane! 


Sunday, May 29, 2011

Has China’s Bubble Popped?

Is something important because you measure it, or is it measured because it's important? Seth Godin

Some market observers have rightly pointed out to China as a possible principal source of concern.

Given the more mature stage of China’s inflation cycle, for me, she is more prone to a bust than her developed economy contemporaries. A China bubble bust would have a far reaching effect on many economies and on financial markets.

clip_image002

China’s major bellwether the Shanghai index [SHCOMP] has been on a rapid downswing (chart courtesy of Bloomberg) after a major bounce off a key resistance level last April.

The Shanghai index seems on path to test its critical support levels on what seems as a pennant chart formation.

The SHCOMP has been on tight trading range since its meltdown from the October 2007 peak at the 6,000 levels. From the said zenith, the index trades at loss of about 52% based on Friday’s close.

And following this week’s 5% rout, the Shanghai index has been down 3.5% on a year to date basis.

Chinese authorities have been tightening monetary policies to curb heightened risks of inflation.

According to a Bloomberg report[1],

The government has increased reserve requirements for banks 11 times and boosted interest rates four times since the start of 2010 to cool consumer prices

And if we go by the conditions of money supply as potential barometer to China’s economic directions, then it would appear that these compounded efforts against further ballooning of the evolving bubble may have began to affect the economy.

clip_image004

China’s falling money supply (right) appears to have triggered a slowdown on import growth, while consumer prices are also expected to decline according to a Danske Bank report[2].

As an aside, another option which China seems to have used on her fight against inflation has been to reduce her holdings of US treasuries for the fifth month[3] (but added on Japanese debts) and subsequently allowed for her currency the yuan to appreciate[4]. All these could also have added to the China’s process to “normalize” her monetary environment which translates to a potential slowdown.

In a discourse about current state of the US economy Austrian economist Dr. Frank Shostak writes[5],

Ultimately it is fluctuations in the growth momentum of the money supply that set in motion fluctuations in the pace of formations of bubble activities. As a result, various bubble activities that emerged on the back of the rising growth momentum of the money supply will come under pressure — an economic bust will be set into motion.

The above tenet has a universal application which means this applies to China as well.

And a possible evidence of such dynamics could be signs of deceleration in some segments of China’s property sector.

clip_image005

Residential sales in the elite or first tier cities have been on a downtrend.

According to the US Global Investors[6],

Residential house sales are seeing a slowdown in major Chinese cities this year. With the tightening of lending to property developers and restriction of purchases by the governments in China, developers are forced to raise money by selling at lower prices.

However, the current slowdown has not been apparent on China’s yield curve (as shown below[7]), which appears to have even steepened—manifesting signs of further inflation ahead.

clip_image007

Unlike Vietnam, whose unfolding stock market crash[8] appears to have dramatically flatten her yield curve over a short time span and seem to emit early signs of tipping over to an inversion (where long term interest rate are lower than the short term)—which could presage a recession over the coming year or so.

China’s immensely high rate of savings (as shown in the below chart[9]), has contributed substantially to the deferment of the unraveling of its policy induced homegrown bubble.

clip_image009

For as long as these savings would be able to finance economic activities that are both productive or not, the bubble activities may continue.

Nonetheless continued exposure to non-productive activities or malinvestments will eventually lead to wealth or capital consumption or the erosion of the pool of real savings which will force a painful adjustment via crisis or recession.

For now, predicting a bursting of China’s bubble may seem tricky. And I won’t tread on this path yet.

Aside from the yield curve, commodities prices appear to be rebounding, which according to the global-emerging market consumption demand story[10], China plays a significant role in the setting of prices.

clip_image011

Besides, the BRIC (Brazil Russia India China) story seems to share quite a strong correlation (except for Russia) in terms of stock market performance. The vertical lines exhibits the near simultaneous important turns on their respective benchmarks.

With signs that Brazil (BVSP), India (BSE) and Russia (RTSE) recently bouncing off their lows along with the current signs of recovery in commodity prices, China could as well experience an oversold rebound and return to its trading range.

Nevertheless I would need to see more signs or evidences of accelerated deterioration on several markets or economic indicators from which to predict (and take necessary action) on the imminence of a recession or a bubble busting environment.

For now, China’s market volatility could just be representative of the correction phase seen in many of the key global equity markets.


[1] Bloomberg.com China Stocks May Extend Slump, ICBC Credit Suisse, Goldman Say, May 24, 2011

[2] Danske Research China: Growth slows but inflation eased less than expected, May 11, 2011

[3] People’s Daily Online China trimmed holdings of US debt again, May 18, 2011

[4] Bloomberg.com Yuan Completes Weekly Gain on Signs Appreciation to Be Allowed, May 27, 2011

[5] Shostak Frank The Effects of Freezing the Balance Sheet, Mises.org, May 20, 2011

[6] US Global Investors Investor Alert, May 27, 2011

[7] asianbondsonline.adb.org, China, People’s Republic of

[8] See Vietnam Stock Market Plunges on Monetary Tightening, May 24, 2011

[9] Chamon, Marcos Liu, Kai Prasad, Eswar The puzzle of China’s rising household saving rate voxeu.org, January 18, 2011

[10] See War On Commodities: China Joins Fray, Global Commodity Politics Intensifies, May 14, 2011

Sunday, February 15, 2009

Fruits From Creative Destruction: An Asian and Emerging Market Decoupling?

``But innovation, in Schumpeter’s famous phrase, is also “creative destruction”. It makes obsolete yesterday’s capital equipment and capital investment. The more the economy progresses, the more capital formation will it therefore need. Thus, the classical economist-or the accountant or the stock exchange-considers “profit” is a genuine cost, the cost of staying in business, the cost of a future in which nothing is predictable except that today’s profitable business will become tomorrow’s white elephant.”- Peter F. Drucker, Profit’s Function, The Daily Drucker.

We read from creditwritedowns.com that Morgan Stanley Asia Chairman Stephen Roach made some predictions, namely:

1 “Asia will have a less acute impact from the global financial and economic crisis”

2. “Export-led regions are followers, not leaders.” Hence would recover after their main export markets, the US and Europe, recovered.

3. “The only possibility (to recover earlier) is China, as it has large infrastructure spending in place that could provide support for economic growth.”

Dr. Roach has been one of the unassuming well respected contrarian voices, whom I have followed, who sternly warned of this crisis.

Nonetheless while we agree with some of his prognosis, where we depart with Dr. Roach is on the aspect of a ‘belated recovery’ of Asia because of its “export dependence” on US and Europe.

Creative Destruction: The Telephone Destroyed The Telegraph

While it is true that the Asian model had functioned as an export-led region over the past years, our favorite cliché, ``Past performance does not guarantee future results” would possibly come into play in the transformation of the playing field.

Let us simplify, if a business paradigm doesn’t work do you insist on pursuing the same model or do you attempt a shift?

Marketing Guru Seth Godin has a terse but poignant depiction of “solving a different problem” response to our question. We quote the terrific guru Mr. Godin,

``The telephone destroyed the telegraph.

``Here's why people liked the telegraph: It was universal, inexpensive, asynchronous and it left a paper trail.

``The telephone offered not one of these four attributes. It was far from universal, and if someone didn't have a phone, you couldn't call them. It was expensive, even before someone called you. It was synchronous--if you weren't home, no call got made. And of course, there was no paper trail.

``If the telephone guys had set out to make something that did what the telegraph does, but better, they probably would have failed. Instead, they solved a different problem, in such an overwhelmingly useful way that they eliminated the feature set of the competition.” (bold highlight mine)

In short, we see human action basically at work. To quote Ludwig von Mises, ``Action is an attempt to substitute a more satisfactory state of affairs for a less satisfactory one. We call such a willfully induced alteration an exchange.”

People who relied on old models didn’t see this coming. They would have resisted until they were overwhelmed.

The fact is the telephone replaced an entrenched system. Joseph Schumpeter, in economic vernacular coined this as “creative destruction”. And creative destruction essentially leads to new operating environments: the rise of the telephone.

Similarly, the Asian export model has been built upon the US credit bubble structure. That bubble is presently deflating and would most possibly dissipate. So is it with Europe’s model.

In other words, the global economy’s trade and investment framework will probably reconfigure based on the present operating economic realities. Countries and regions would probably operate under a set of redefined roles.

Here are three clues of the possible creative destruction transformation.

Deepening Regionalism


Figure 3: ADB: Emerging Asian Regionalism

This from the ADB’s Emerging Asian Regionalism, ``In large part due to the growth of production networks just discussed, trade within Asia has increased from 37% of its total trade in 1986 to 52% in 2006 (Figure 3.3). The share of trade with Europe has risen somewhat, while that with the US and the rest of the world has fallen. As set out in Chapter 2, Asia’s intraregional trade share is now midway between Europe’s and North America’s. It is also higher than Europe’s was at the outset of its integration process in the early 1960s.

``But trade has not been diverted from the rest of the world. On the contrary, trade with each of Asia’s four main partner groups has increased in the last two decades—not just absolutely, but also relative to Asia’s GDP (Figure 3.4). For example, Asia’s trade with the EU has more than doubled as a share of its GDP, from 2.6% in 1986 to 6.0% in 2006. The increase is even larger as a share of the EU’s GDP. The aggregate trade data thus suggests that Asia is steadily integrating both regionally and globally.”

The fact is that Asia has steadily been regionalizing or developing its intraregional dynamics even when the bubble structure had been functional. Today’s imploding bubble isn’t likely to alter such deepening trend.

Moreover, the current unwinding bubble structure is emblematic of a discoordination process from a ‘market clearing’ environment.

Under this phase, spare capacities are being shut or sold, excess labor are being laid off, surplus inventories are being liquidated and losses are being realized. Essentially new players are taking over the affected industries. And new players will be coming in with fresh capital to replace those whom have lost. Fresh capital will come from those economies with large savings or unimpaired banking system (see Will Deglobalization Lead To Decoupling?)

And like any economic cycles, this adjustment process will lead to equilibrium. Eventually a trough will be reached, where demand and supply should balance out and a transition to recovery follows.

The post bubble structure is likely to reinforce and not reduce this intraregional dynamic.

So in contrast to the notion of a belated recovery in Asia hinged on the old decrepit model, a China recovery should lift the rest of Asia out of the doldrums.

Asia and not the old stewards should lead the recovery based on the new paradigm.

And in every new bullmarket there always has been a change in market leadership. We are probably witnessing the incipience of such change today.

Real Savings Function As Basic Consumption

The assumption of the intransigence of Asia as an export led model is predicated on Keynesian theory of aggregate demand. In essence, for as long as borrowing and lending won’t recover in the traditional ‘aggregate demand’ economies, there won’t be a recovery in export led economies.

But in contrast to such consensus view, demand is not our problem, production from savings is.

According to quote Dr. Frank Shostak, ``At any point in time, the amount of goods and services available are finite. This is not so with regard to people’s demand, which tends to be unlimited. Most people want as many things as they can think of. What thwarts their demand is the availability of means. Hence, there can never be a problem with demand as such, but with the means to accommodate demand.

``Moreover, no producer is preoccupied with demand in general, but rather with the demand for his particular goods.”

``In the real world, one has to become a producer before one can demand goods and services. It is necessary to produce some useful goods that can be exchanged for other goods.”

A sole shipwrecked survivor in an island will need to scour for food and water in order to consume. This means he/she can only consume from what can be produced (catch or harvest). It goes the same in a barter economy; a baker can only have his pair of shoes if he trades his spare breads with surplus of shoes made by the shoemaker.

Surplus bread or shoes or produce, thus, constitute as real savings. And to expand production, the shoemaker, the baker or even the shipwrecked survivor would need to invest their surpluses or savings to achieve more output which enables them to spend more in the future.

Instead of getting x amounts of coconuts required for daily nourishment, the shipwrecked survivor will acquire a week’s harvest and use his spare time to make a knife so he can either make ladder (to improve output), build a boat (to catch fish or to go home) or to hunt animals (to alter diet) or to make a shelter (for convenience). Essentially savings allows the survivor to improve on his/her living conditions.

To increase production for the goal of increasing future consumption, the savings of both the shoemaker and the baker would likely be invested in new equipment (capital goods).

Again to quote Dr. Shostak (bold highlight mine), ``What limits the production growth of goods and services is the introduction of better tools and machinery (i.e., capital goods), which raises worker productivity. Tools and machinery are not readily available; they must be made. In order to make them, people must allocate consumer goods and services that will sustain those individuals engaged in the production of tools and machinery.

``This allocation of consumer goods and services is what savings is all about. Note that savings become possible once some individuals have agreed to transfer some of their present goods to individuals that are engaged in the production of tools and machinery. Obviously, they do not transfer these goods for free, but in return for a greater quantity of goods in the future. According to Mises, "Production of goods ready for consumption requires the use of capital goods, that is, of tools and of half-finished material. Capital comes into existence by saving, i.e., temporary abstention from consumption.”

``Since saving enables the production of capital goods, saving is obviously at the heart of the economic growth that raises people's living standards. On this Mises wrote, “Saving and the resulting accumulation of capital goods are at the beginning of every attempt to improve the material condition of man; they are the foundation of human civilization.”

So what changes this primitive way of production-consumption to mainstream’s consumption-production framework?

The answer is debt. Debt can be used in productive or non-productive spending. But debt today is structured based on the modern central banking.

Think credit card. Credit card allows everyone to extend present consumption patterns by charging to future income. If debt is continually spent on non-productive items, it eventually chafes on one’s capacity to pay. It consumes equity. Eventually, overindulgence in non productive debt leads bankruptcy. And this epitomizes today’s crisis.

But debt issued from real savings can’t lead to massive clustering of errors (bubble burst) because they are limited and based on production surpluses. It is non productive debt issued from ‘something out of nothing’ or the fractional banking system combined with loose monetary policies from interest manipulations that skews the lending incentives and enables massive malinvestments.

To aptly quote Mr. Peter Schiff’s analysis of today’s crisis, ``Credit, whether securitized or not, cannot be created out of thin air. It only comes into existence though savings, which must be preceded by under-consumption. Since savings are scarce, any government guarantees toward consumer credit merely crowd out credit that might otherwise have been available to business. During the previous decade too much credit was extended to consumers and not enough to producers (securitization focused almost exclusively on consumer debt). The market is trying to correct this misallocation, but government policy is standing in the way. When consumers borrow and spend, society gains nothing. When producers borrow and invest, our capital stock is improved, and we all benefit from the increased productivity.”

Now if capital comes into existence by virtue of savings, we should ask where most of the savings are located?

The answer is in Asia and emerging markets.

Figure 4: Matthews Asian Fund: Asia Insight

According to Winnie Puah of Matthews Asia, ``The economic potential and impact of Asian savings have yet to be fully unleashed at home. Indeed, Asia’s excess savings fuelled the recent boom in U.S. consumption and housing markets. Creating a consumption boom in Asia would mean that Asia needs to borrow and spend more. To date, governments are supporting domestic demand with fiscal stimulus packages—but it is household balance sheets that hold the key to developing a consumer culture. Overall, Asian households are well-positioned to increase spending—most have low debt levels and high rates of savings… there is a noticeable divergence in saving patterns between emerging and mature economies over the past decade, particularly since Asia learned a hard lesson from being overleveraged during the Asian financial crisis. Today, most Asian households save 10%—30% of their disposable incomes. China’s households, for example, have over US$3 trillion in savings deposits but have borrowed only US$500 billion.”

Thus I wouldn’t underestimate the power of Asia’s savings that could be converted or transformed into spending.

Asia’s Tsunami of Middle Class Consumers

In my August 2008 article Decoupling Recoupling Debate As A Religion, we noted of the theory called as the “Acceleration Phenomenon” developed by French economist Aftalion, who propounded that a marginal increase in the income distribution of heavily populated countries as China, based on a Gaussian pattern, can potentially unleash a torrent of middle class consumers.

Apparently, the Economist recently published a similar but improvised version of the Acceleration Phenomenon model. And based on this, the Economist says that 57% of the world population is now living in middle class standards (see figure 5)!


Figure 5: The Economist: The Rise of the Middle Class?

From The Economist (bold highlights mine), ``In practice, emerging markets may be said to have two middle classes. One consists of those who are middle class by any standard—ie, with an income between the average Brazilian and Italian. This group has the makings of a global class whose members have as much in common with each other as with the poor in their own countries. It is growing fast, but still makes up only a tenth of the developing world. You could call it the global middle class.

``The other, more numerous, group consists of those who are middle-class by the standards of the developing world but not the rich one. Some time in the past year or two, for the first time in history, they became a majority of the developing world’s population: their share of the total rose from one-third in 1990 to 49% in 2005. Call it the developing middle class.

``Using a somewhat different definition—those earning $10-100 a day, including in rich countries—an Indian economist, Surjit Bhalla, also found that the middle class’s share of the whole world’s population rose from one-third to over half (57%) between 1990 and 2006. He argues that this is the third middle-class surge since 1800. The first occurred in the 19th century with the creation of the first mass middle class in western Europe. The second, mainly in Western countries, occurred during the baby boom (1950-1980). The current, third one is happening almost entirely in emerging countries. According to Mr Bhalla’s calculations, the number of middle-class people in Asia has overtaken the number in the West for the first time since 1700.”

So apparently, today’s phenomenon seems strikingly similar to Seth Godin’s description of the creative destruction of the telegraph.

The seeds of the rising middle class appear to emanate from the wealth transfer from the developed Western economies to Asia and emerging markets. Put differently, Asia and EM economies could be the fruits from the recent ‘creative destruction’.

Some Emerging Signs?

However, there are always two sides to a coin.

For some, the present crisis signify as a potential regression of these resurgent middle class to their poverty stricken state, as the major economies slumps and drag the entire world into a vortex.

For us, substantial savings or capital (the key to consumption), deepening regionalism, underutilized or untapped credit facilities, rapidly developing financial markets, a huge middle class, unimpaired banking system, and most importantly policies dedicated to economic freedom serve as the proverbial line etched in the sand.

One might add that the negative interest rates or low interest policies and the spillage effect from stimulus programs from developed economies appear to percolate into the financial systems of Asia and emerging markets.

Although these are inherently long term trends, we sense some emergent short term signs which may corroborate this view:

1. Despite the 30% slump in the global Mergers and Acquisitions in 2008, China recorded a 44% jump to $159 billion mostly to foreign telecommunication and foreign parts makers (Korea Times). Japan M&A soared last year to a record $165 billion in 2008 a 13% increase (Bloomberg).

2. Credit environment seems to be easing substantially.

According to FinanceAsia (Bold highlights), ``The fallout from Japan's banking crisis offers clues to how the current situation may resolve itself. Back then, healing started first in the areas that had been most affected -- interbank lending recovered earliest, followed by credit markets, volatility markets and finally, many years later, equity markets.

``In today's crisis, interbank lending is already starting to recover. The spread between three-month interbank lending rates and overnight rates, which provides a key measure of the health of credit markets, has dropped significantly from its peak of 364bp in early 2008 down to less than 100bp today. As the interbank market recovers, credit should be next to heal.

``However, at the moment, triple-B spreads are at their highest levels in more than 100 years, which makes credit look like an extremely attractive investment opportunity. And there is every reason to expect that Asian corporates will participate in the healing, perhaps even as quickly as their counterparts in the US. (Oops and I thought everyone said divergence wasn’t possible or decoupling is a myth)

3. Asian companies have begun to engage in debt buyback. Again from FinanceAsia, ``Asian companies are buying back their debt with gusto and this could be a sign that credit markets are on the mend, according to Morgan Stanley.

``Asian companies are betting that credit will offer the best returns in 2009 and, like the smart traders they are, executives in the region are busy buying back their debt with gusto.

4. A picture speaks a thousand words…


Figure 6: A BRIC Decoupling?

China and Brazil appear to be leading the BRIC recovery while India (BSE) and Russia (RTS) seem to initiating their own.

For financial markets of developed economies, don’t speak of bad words.