Showing posts with label inflation stages. Show all posts
Showing posts with label inflation stages. Show all posts

Thursday, February 06, 2014

Inflation is a process: 1960-80 Edition

One observation I recently received concerned about how US Federal Reserve policies allegedly produced an “immediate inflation” in the 1970s (via stagflation) while today’s massive over $4 trillion of balance sheet expansion as of December 2013 hasn’t produced the same effect.

image
graphics via the CNN

Well inflation don’t just appear, like a genie, from nowhere. Inflation is a process.

This applies as well to during the 1960s to 1980s

From Wikipedia: (bold mine)
In 1944, the Bretton Woods system fixed exchange rates based on the U.S. dollar, which was redeemable for gold by the U.S. government at the price of $35 per ounce. Thus, the United States was committed to backing every dollar overseas with gold. Other currencies were fixed to the dollar, and the dollar was pegged to gold.

For the first years after World War II, the Bretton Woods system worked well. With the Marshall Plan Japan and Europe were rebuilding from the war, and foreigners wanted dollars to spend on American goods – cars, steel, machinery, etc. Because the U.S. owned over half the world's official gold reserves – 574 million ounces at the end of World War II – the system appeared secure.

However, from 1950 to 1969, as Germany and Japan recovered, the US share of the world's economic output dropped significantly, from 35 percent to 27 percent. Furthermore, a negative balance of payments, growing public debt incurred by the Vietnam War and Great Society programs, and monetary inflation by the Federal Reserve caused the dollar to become increasingly overvalued in the 1960s. The drain on US gold reserves culminated with the London Gold Pool collapse in March 1968.

By 1971, America's gold stock had fallen to $10 billion, half its 1960 level. Foreign banks held many more dollars than the U.S. held gold, leaving the U.S. vulnerable to a run on its gold.

By 1971, the money supply had increased by 10%. In May 1971, West Germany was the first to leave the Bretton Woods system, unwilling to devalue the Deutsche Mark in order to prop up the dollar. In the following three months, this move strengthened its economy. Simultaneously, the dollar dropped 7.5% against the Deutsche Mark. Other nations began to demand redemption of their dollars for gold. Switzerland redeemed $50 million in July. France acquired $191 million in gold. On August 5, 1971, the United States Congress released a report recommending devaluation of the dollar, in an effort to protect the dollar against "foreign price-gougers". On August 9, 1971, as the dollar dropped in value against European currencies, Switzerland left the Bretton Woods system. The pressure began to intensify on the United States to leave Bretton Woods.

image

The above chart from economagic reveals that price inflation didn’t just “appear”. 

The US government had already indulged in monetary inflation as far back in the advent of the 1960s (as seen via M2 blue line). Meanwhile price inflation (CPI red line) began its upward trek only 5 years after. (both are measured via % change from a year ago).

When the Bretton Woods era came to a close, US M2 soared in two occasions. This  led to accompanying spikes in CPI which resulted to ‘stagflationary’ recessions.

Former Fed Chair Paul Volcker was widely credited for wringing out inflation by massively raising interest rates. Although Dr. Marc Faber already noted that the supply side glut from the early inflation has began to impact prices and that Mr. Volcker’s action may have complimented on this adjustment phase. The US economy had 3 agonizing recessions in the late 1970s to the early 1980s following the monetary experiment from the Nixon Shock before the imbalances brought about by previous monetary inflation had been reversed.

The point is inflation is a process which undergoes different stages

As the late Austrian economist Percy Greaves Jr. explained in simple layman terms
The first stage of inflation is when housewives say: "Prices are going up. I think I had better put off buying whatever I can. I need a new vacuum cleaner, but with prices going up, I'll wait until they come down." During this stage, prices do not rise as fast as the quantity of money is being increased. This period in the great German inflation lasted nine years, from the outbreak of war in 1914 until the summer of 1923.

During the second period of inflation, housewives say: "I shall need a vacuum cleaner next year. Prices are going up. I had better get it now before prices go any higher." During this stage, prices rise at a faster rate than the quantity of money is being increased. In Germany this period lasted a couple of months.

If the inflation is not stopped, the third stage follows. In this third stage, housewives say: "I don't like flowers. They bother me. They are a nuisance. But I would rather have even this pot of flowers than hold on to this money a moment longer." People then exchange their money for anything they can get. This period may last from 24 hours to 48 hours.
From the US ‘stagflationary’ experience, market developments combined with policy actions prevented the third stage (crack-up) boom from transpiring. But the policy tradeoff had been to induce harrowing periods of recessions.

Some notes:

-The foundation of the stagflation era of 1970s went as far back to the inflationary policies by the Fed during the early 1960s. The sustained inflationist policies eventually led to consumer price inflation.

-US inflationist policies largely due to the Vietnam war and US welfare (New Society) programs put an end to the Bretton Woods Standards.

-Recessions are necessary to reverse previous monetary abuse. The Bust serve as necessary medicine and therapy for the inflationary boom ailment.

There are also other factors that influence price inflation. For one, productivity growth from globalization helped reduced the impact of US Federal Reserve policies in the post Volcker era. This has been wrongly construed as the Great Moderation.

The massive explosion in the growth of the asset markets supported by debt that have also been instrumental in shifting the nature of the impact of inflation since a lot of monetary inflation today have been absorbed by asset markets (trillion dollar derivatives, bond markets, currency markets, etc...).

Bottom line: Just because statistical consumer price inflation seem subdued today, doesn’t mean there won’t be price inflation tomorrow or sometime in the future.

As one would note from the experience of the 1970s when price inflation emerges, it comes rather quickly

And in my view, the highly volatile financial markets today are symptoms such transition, but in a different light: asset inflation boom morphing into asset bust.

The next question is how will central bankers and the government react? Will their response lead to a crack-up boom (ruination of a currency via hyperinflation) or deflationary depression? I call this the von Mises Moment

Monday, October 28, 2013

Phisix: ASEAN Equity Markets Continue to Lag

It has been a curiosity for me to see ASEAN equity markets, with the exception of Malaysia, fail to rev up along with high octane US and some European markets as the German Dax, considering an environment of falling US dollar and a reprieve from the bond vigilantes.

Global Trade Woes?

Could it be because of growing concerns on global trade particularly from export dependent Asia?

clip_image001

According to a Bloomberg report[1],
The Hague-based CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis estimated global trade volume fell 0.8 percent in August, eroding a 1.8 percent jump of the previous month. It was the weakest performance since a 1.1 percent decline in February and left the three-month average lagging its historical pace.
While global merchandise trade remains slightly off record highs, the rate of gains has been on a decline (quarter on quarter—left) and (quarter from a year ago—right)[2],

Much of the failing trade has been attributed to the ‘lack of demand’ from emerging markets. But the article did not bother to explain further.

Unlike mainstream view, the slowing growth in emerging markets has mainly been a product of internal bubbles, many of whom have been approaching their inflection points. The threat by the US Fed to “taper” last May only exposed on these vulnerabilities. 

In addition, the adverse consequences from the largely unseen redistribution of resources from US Federal Reserve policies which has been embraced as the de facto operating standard by global central banks seem as becoming more evident.

Credit easing policies such as zero bound rates has gradually been eroding on the real savings of many Asian nations who adapted such schemes. Borrowing demand from the future financed by debt has come home to roost.

And since inflationism has been designed to transfer resources to privileged constituents or to protect certain interest groups at the expense of the rest, the corollary inequalities have led to politically charged atmosphere.

And in the realm of politics, the intuitive and the best way to divert the public’s attention from the real issue have been to blame the foreigners. 

In doing so, inflationism which usually is followed by price controls eventually spawns trade, finance and labor protectionism.

So the next political actions we should expect would be travel or social mobility restrictions, higher tariffs or more non-tariff trade barriers and capital controls.

The same article suggests that we are headed in such direction.
Protectionism is also on the rise despite pledges to avoid it by the Group of 20 leading industrial and developing economies, according to Evenett. He estimates 337 measures have been imposed worldwide so far this year after 503 in 2012.
However, near record high New Zealand stocks and record high Malaysian and Australian stocks can hardly explain the global trade factor.

Credit Concerns?

The other factor causing such divergence could be slowing credit growth.
clip_image002

As pointed out above, internal bubbles have served as an internal hindrance to expanding credit growth.

A survey from the Institute of International Finance[3] (IIF) on Emerging Markets suggests that “bank lending conditions continued to tighten in emerging economies for the second quarter in a row.”

And while demand for loans in Asia seem to have improved, credit standards, funding conditions and trade finance have all meaningfully slowed.

clip_image003

The IIF data actually mostly reflects on the credit conditions of the Philippine banking system, based on the BSP data from the start of the year until August. Except that credit growth in August appear to have rebounded, despite the “Ghost Month” which curiously the BSP incorporates as “economic” analysis.

[As a side note, the BSP’s stubborn insistence to use “Ghost Month”[4] assumes that whether Filipino or Chinese or foreign non-Chinese, all subscribe to such superstition. Based on such logic, perhaps ‘paranormal’ forces had been responsible for the credit growth last August]

I have no data yet for September to see whether the August loan rebound has been sustained or had been a blip.

I have yet to access credit data conditions for Malaysia, Australia and New Zealand, but have been limited by time constraints

Capricious Credit Rating Agencies

Credit rating agency Fitch has revised their outlook on Malaysia to Negative from Stable in July, they further warned about the growing pressure on credit profiles of Asia-Pacific Sovereigns[5]

The Standard & Poors seem to have seconded such concerns where “positive trend of Asia-Pacific sovereign ratings”, said KimEng Tan, senior director for Standard & Poor’s Ratings Services in an interview[6], “over much of the past decade looks likely to break in the next one or two years. We do not see a high likelihood of a sovereign rating upgrade during that period. Instead, three sovereign ratings in the region currently carry negative outlooks – India, Japan and Mongolia. We do not have any Asia-Pacific sovereign on a positive outlook.” (bold mine)

It is ironic how Malaysia’s July downside revision has led to new record high stocks while the trifecta of credit rating upgrades have still left the Phisix midway from the distance of the recent historic highs and the meltdown lows.

Importantly both credit rating agencies appear to be “playing safe”, such that in the event that another market meltdown episode, they would have the leeway to immediately initiate downgrades.

As pointed out before[7], credit rating agencies have essentially been reactionary. They respond to market events rather than take action in antecedence. They hardly see risks coming. Two market meltdowns appear to have altered their sanguine viewpoints on the region. Yet as a sign of dithering, they refrain from actual downgrades but instead float trial balloons by verbalizing their concerns.

In the case of the S&P, they have placed on negative outlook, for instance the S&P on India, Japan and Mongolia. Paradoxically, like Fitch on Malaysia, India’s stocks are also a breath away off from the recent landmark highs.

This also reveals of the narrowness of the span of vision of credit rating agencies has for their subjects, or in this case the sovereigns, such that they easily change sentiments.

The above also suggests of the extreme volatility of the markets as they become detached with fundamentals.

The China Wild Card: Has Inflation Reached a Critical State?

It is hard to see the Chinese card on ASEAN when Australian stocks are at record territories and when the Australian dollar have strengthened (except for the past three days)

But again, it’s hard to see a straight connection based on economic fundamentals when financial markets have been heavily distorted by excessive politicization.

My goal here will not be explain past stock market actions, but rather to anticipate the potential actions given the recent events.

clip_image004

The Chinese government has reportedly suspended three consecutive sessions of reverse repurchase operations.

This has supposedly impelled a spike in the Chinese interest rate markets. Shibor rates (Shanghai Interbank Offered Rates[8]) interest rates representing unsecured short term interbank money markets have soared across the maturity spectrum. The overnight (left most), the 6 months (middle) and 1 year (right most)[9] have all surged.

Friday, yields of China’s 10 year bonds hit 4.23% but closed back at 4.16% the highest since November 2007 when it peaked at 4.6%[10]

Part of the cause has been attributed to “financial and tax paid in October” which contributed to tightening conditions.

While the Chinese government has taken new steps to liberalize interest rates last week where banks rather than the PBOC would set benchmark[11], I don’t think the new interest rate regime has anything to do with the turmoil.

One domestic google translated English article[12] noted that the market is said to be worried about "money shortage", since “excessive tightening of liquidity could lead to systemic risk”. The article mentioned money shortage thrice.

Another google translated English article[13] noted of the same “market money shortage recurrence concerns”, but this time, the quoted expert raised inflation rate and housing prices as contributing to the tightening.

When people complain about “shortages of money”, they could be expressing signs of acceleration of inflation, where changes in the supply of money have been deemed as insufficient to meet changes in money prices. Put differently such represents an advance phase of inflationism.

As the dean of the Austrian school of economics, Murray Rothbard explained[14] (bold mine)
At first, when prices rise, people say: "Well, this is abnormal, the product of some emergency. I will postpone my purchases and wait until prices go back down." This is the common attitude during the first phase of an inflation. This notion moderates the price rise itself, and conceals the inflation further, since the demand for money is thereby increased. But, as inflation proceeds, people begin to realize that prices are going up perpetually as a result of perpetual inflation. Now people will say: "I will buy now, though prices are `high,' because if I wait, prices will go up still further." As a result, the demand for money now falls and prices go up more, proportionately, than the increase in the money supply. At this point, the government is often called upon to "relieve the money shortage" caused by the accelerated price rise, and it inflates even faster. Soon, the country reaches the stage of the "crack-up boom," when people say: "I must buy anything now--anything to get rid of money which depreciates on my hands." The supply of money skyrockets, the demand plummets, and prices rise astronomically. Production falls sharply, as people spend more and more of their time finding ways to get rid of their money. The monetary system has, in effect, broken down completely, and the economy reverts to other moneys, if they are attainable--other metal, foreign currencies if this is a one-country inflation, or even a return to barter conditions. The monetary system has broken down under the impact of inflation.
If the Chinese government really thinks that inflation has gotten out of control then the thrust to tighten may continue. However such tightening could mean bursting of many highly leveraged businesses. This also means that credit woes will spread via the periphery to the core dynamic, given China’s highly leveraged the formal and informal banking system. In short boom could turn into a massive bust.

It is unclear how determined and how much pain and pressures the Chinese political leadership can withstand.

But if it is true that China’s system has reached an advanced phase in terms of inflation and if the Chinese government accommodates the demand for money to ease the shortages then China may experience a Venezuela.

clip_image006

This has been the second time the Chinese government has attempted to curb liquidity.

The first time was in June where China’s credit turmoil caused a stir in Asian markets (blue lines).

While global markets as Australia appears to have discounted the Chinese turbulence as perhaps just another typical quirk, we will have to see or ascertain if the economic conditions has really deteriorated. Japan’s Nikkei appears to be weakening again coincidental with the Chinese benchmark.

The following days will be critical.

If the problems in China have turned unwieldy then another round of a market meltdown can’t be discounted.

As I have been lately saying, there are many flashpoints or minefields around the world that could spell the difference between one’s return ON investments as against return OF investments.





[3] Institute of International Finance Emerging Markets Bank Lending Conditions Survey - 2013Q3 October 24, 2013











[14] Murray N. Rothbard, 2. The Economic Effects of Inflation Government Meddling With Money What Has Government Done to Our Money?

Monday, June 24, 2013

Phisix in the Shadows of a Bursting Global Bond Market Bubble

The capital markets are desperate for continued hallucination. Central banks supply hallucinations. They create money, and the investing world pretends that this is capital. It isn’t capital. It is no more capital than heroin is a nutrient. Heroin is a tool for keeping people from coming to grips with reality. So is central bank monetary inflation. –Gary North

Mainstream Talking Points: The Irrelevance of Easy Money

Thursday’s Inquirer article opened with how the domestic financial markets had been shaken from a supposed turnaround in US monetary policies: “US Federal Reserve signaled that the regime of easy money—which has inflated asset valuations in emerging markets—would end by next year”[1].

Ironically the entire article went on to refute, or more appropriately, defend the status quo by sidestepping the issue of how “easy money” led to “inflated asset valuations”. The stereotyped politically tinged article cites the opinions of “economic managers” whose arguments banked on supposed “fundamentals”.

Such assurances comically emanate from talking heads who never saw this financial market rout coming in the first place.

The populist dogma feted by mainstream media to the public has been to project a “new order” for the Philippine markets and the economy whose direction has been etched on the stone as “up up and away!”.

Yet for the mainstream “experts” and the populist talking heads, recent events has been deemed as an anomaly, a temporal quirk, unreal or a just a metaphorical nightmare—which will go away soon.

Since such events don’t fit into their understanding of the world, which for them reality or “fundamentals” constitute as statistical aggregates, the natural reaction has been to deny them.

The bubble mentality has been so pronounced to the point that some experts even justify high valuations[2] of Philippines assets relative to other Asian peers due to “strong growth trajectory” and “long term growth prospects”. This time is different.

Such denials basically ignore the fact that market actions account for as “fundamentals”, they have been portentous of a dramatic change of economic-financial and even political environment.

Would sellers stampede out of or crash the markets without any motivations guiding their actions? Such would represent naïve presumptiveness.

Perhaps humongous political rallies in Brazil[3], Indonesia[4], and Turkey[5] could be writings on the wall.

If the transition from easy money to tight money will be sustained, then all of the inflated statistics from which current “fundamentals” (yes history) have been founded on, hence the “inflated asset valuations”, will dramatically get reconfigured.

Moreover, the obsession over accounting identities as impeccable measures of economic growth will be blown to smithereens or exposed for as duplicitous aggregates tainted by patent imperfections.

Heuristics camouflaged by economic terminologies and statistics hardly constitutes as economic analysis.

Popular delusions of “this time is different” brought about by credit expansion will face harsh reality soon.

Signs of Bursting Bond Bubble?

The mainstream cannot seem to fathom that monetary policies are hardly neutral and has relative impacts on each sectors of the economy.

They hardly understand or appreciate the causal relationship between monetary conditions with respect to asset markets, statistical economy and the real economy.

My guidepost from the start of the year[6]:
Let me repeat: the direction of the Phisix and the Peso will ultimately be determined by the direction of domestic interest rates which will likewise reflect on global trends.
And interest rates have indeed shaped the market’s direction.

clip_image002
CLIMBING yields of the US 10 year treasury, which serves as important benchmarks for many credit markets, has accelerated or has intensified from its interim nadir last May.

Once the yields broke beyond the March highs of 2.05%, global markets began to seize up as shown by the recent decline of the S&P, and the nosedive in the Phsix (PCOMP) and ex-US global equity benchmark (MSCI World).

Last Friday, UST’s 10 year yields spiked to August 2011 levels[7].

clip_image004

The upheaval in US bond markets[8] has been broad based.

The biggest impact can mostly be seen in UST 5-10 year notes and the 30 year bonds as well as the Treasury Inflation Protected Securities (TIPs) [lower pane].

Rising yields of TIPs suggest that the market’s expectation of inflation risks have, so far, been subdued.

Add to this recent surge of credit default swap premiums[9] both in the sovereign and corporate sector which underlies growing concerns over creditworthiness, it would seem a mistake to construe rising yields as a function of “economic growth”.

Instead the unraveling events seem as growing indications of concerns over credit quality conditions.

Bluntly put, we could be witnessing incipient signs of the bursting of global financial asset bubbles, spearheaded by the bond markets.

Fed Communique: To Taper or To Ease?

I would like to reemphasize too that the Ben Bernanke’s “Taper talk” really has substantially been a tactical communications signaling maneuver to maintain or preserve the central bank’s “credibility” by realigning policy stance with actions in the bond markets.

clip_image006

The incumbent FED’s easing policies which has been designed to “maintain downward pressure on longer-term interest rates, support mortgage markets, and help to make broader financial conditions more accommodative”[10] has been confronted by the opposite or the unintended effects: rising long term interest rates.

10 year yields have been rising since July 2012. The FED implemented the QEternity 3.0 in September of 2012 which put downward pressure on rates for a mere THREE (3) month period. Yields then reversed course and crept higher until Japan’s PM Shinzo Abe’s nomination of Haruhiko Kuroda as Bank of Japan’s Chief. The appointment of Mr. Kuroda, who was widely expected to conduct aggressive monetary actions, practically served as the “sell on news” part of the “buy the rumor, sell the news” on Mr. Kuroda’s assumption to office. The announcement of Kuroda’s “arrow” of Abenomics plus the ECB’s interest rate cut last May has basically been negated by the ascendant yields.
In short, yields have been rising even before the Taper Talk.

This shows that it would not be accurate to say that Taper Talk caused higher yields. Instead, the Taper Talk essentially functioned as the “trigger” or the “outlet valve” for what has been a simmering pressure buildup for higher yields. The Taper Talk has really been an aggravating factor.

A further reality is that the “Taper Talk” mantra represents as selective focusing of the markets. The markets fixated on one aspect of the FOMC announcement while disregarding the rest.

The Fed’s official communique mentioned “taper” as an option “The Committee is prepared to increase or reduce the pace of its purchases” that is subject to arbitrary parameters set by them “will continue to take appropriate account of the likely efficacy and costs of such purchases as well as the extent of progress toward its economic objectives”.

Taper has not been a foreordained path. To the contrary the increase in the pace of purchases has also been considered or discussed.

This has been reinforced by Mr. Bernanke’s press conference speech[11]:

The Taper Option: (bold mine)
If the incoming data are broadly consistent with this forecast, the Committee currently anticipates that it would be appropriate to moderate the monthly pace of purchases later this year; and if the subsequent data remain broadly aligned with our current expectations for the economy, we would continue to reduce the pace of purchases in measured steps through the first half of next year, ending purchases around midyear. In this scenario, when asset purchases ultimately come to an end, the unemployment rate would likely be in the vicinity of 7 percent, with solid economic growth supporting further job gains, a substantial improvement from the 8.1 percent unemployment rate that prevailed when the Committee announced this program
The Easing Option:
I would like to emphasize once more the point that our policy is in no way predetermined and will depend on the incoming data and the evolution of the outlook, as well as on the cumulative progress toward our objectives. If conditions improve faster than expected, the pace of asset purchases could be reduced somewhat more quickly. If the outlook becomes less favorable, on the other hand, or if financial conditions are judged to be inconsistent with further progress in the labor markets, reductions in the pace of purchases could be delayed; indeed, should it be needed, the Committee would be prepared to employ all of its tools, including an increase in the pace of purchases for a time, to promote a return to maximum employment in a context of price stability
To repeat: The “taper” is an option, and not a definitive action, that the FED may or may not resort to. As much as taper is an option, so has “easing”. 

Bond vigilantes itching for a grand entrance found the Taper speech as opportunity to flaunt their newfound power.

Asked about the “very sharp rise in real interest rates” over the last few weeks, the clueless Bernanke responds
Well, we were a little puzzled by that. It was bigger than it could be explained I think by changes the ultimate stock of asset purchases within reasonable ranges. So I think we have to conclude that there are other factors at work as well including again, some optimism about the economy, maybe some uncertainty arising. So, I'm agreeing with you that seems larger than it can be explained by a changing view of monetary policy. It's difficult to judge whether the markets are in sync or not
Rising yields over the past 11 months depicts of the diminishing marginal returns of such policies. This means that accumulation of current imbalances has essentially offset the wealth generating capacity of the economy or has severely damaged the process of real wealth generation that has led to a shrinkage in real savings.

As Austrian economist Dr. Frank Shostak explains[12]:
Contrary to popular thinking, an increase in the monetary flow is in fact detrimental to economic growth since it sets in motion an exchange of something for nothing — it leads to the diversion of real wealth from wealth generators to wealth consumers. This in the process reduces the amount of wealth at the disposal of wealth generators thereby diminishing their ability to enhance and maintain the infrastructure. This in turn undermines the ability to grow the economy.
Rising yields will either force the FED to align their policies with the bond markets or attempt to douse such conflagration with bigger inflationist policies.

Poker Bluff Redux

clip_image008

The US government and the banking system have become increasingly dependent on Fed’s actions.

The balance sheet of the US Federal Reserve[13] has been stuffed with US Treasuries and mortgage backed securities (MBS)

The Fed possesses about 30.32% of all outstanding ten year an equivalent according to the Zero Hedge[14]. At the rate of purchases, the FED’s share of outstanding ten year will balloon to 90% in 2017, where the Zero hedge notes that “By the end of 2018 there would be no privately held US treasury paper”. And if fiscal deficits do shrink, a complete nationalization of bond markets will be sooner rather than in 2017-2018.

The same almost holds true for mortgages. As Euro Pacific Capital’s Peter Schiff recently pointed out[15], (bold mine)
While it's true that the Fed only owns 14% of all outstanding MBS (the "small fraction" he referred to in the press conference), it is by far the largest purchaser of newly issued mortgage debt. What would happen to the market if the Fed were no longer buying? There are no longer enough private buyers to soak up the issuance. Those who do remain would certainly expect higher yields if the option of selling to the Fed was no longer on the table. Put bluntly, the Fed is the market right now and has been for years.
Given the entrenched dependency relationship by the mortgage markets and by the US government on the US Federal Reserve, the Fed’s QE program can be interpreted as a quasi-fiscal policy whose major beneficiaries have been the political class and the banking class. Thus, there will be little incentives for FED officials to downsize the FED’s actions, unless forced upon by the markets. Since politicians are key beneficiaries from such programs, Fed officials will be subject to political pressures.

This is why I think the “taper talk” represents just one of the FED’s serial poker bluffs.

Besides, any withdrawal or a scaling back of QE will only stir up disorder, not only in the bond markets, but across the financial asset spectrum from which the current market bedlam serves as a useful template.

And in contrast to the popular idea that the FED will taper, again I think that surging interest rates and the attendant intensifying financial market turmoil eventually will impact on the FED’s dual mandate of “maximum employment and price stability”.

While the objective of “price stability”[16] has been focused on price inflation, the ongoing riots in the bond markets are equally signs of spreading instability that will interfere “with the efficient operation of the economy and can reduce economic growth”.

The FED obviously has been looking at the wrong places.

Such reemergent instabilities will compel the FED to expand their balance sheets. And I expect other central bankers to follow suit.

clip_image009
It is important to note too that with the stimulative effects of about $10 trillion[17] of global central bank asset expansion obviously fading, central bankers whom has recently been hailed as “superheroes”[18] for what has been perceived by media as having attained the elixir of policymaking will likely renew their attempt to reflate the markets and economies.

Aside from the political agenda, the previous round of so-called “successes” will provide the motivation for FED and other central bankers to adapt the same “path dependent[19]” recourse.

As I have been repeatedly saying, central bankers will likely push inflationism to the limits: QE 1.0, QE 2.0, QEternity, Abenomics and etc…

And with the diminishing access to what government labels as “risk free” bonds or “safe assets”, which will affect bank capital adequacy regulations and bank risk profiles, central bankers are likely to expand purchases to include other financial assets, perhaps equities, corporate bonds and others.

But there will likely be more pain ahead before the next round of central bank actions.

“Deflation” has been conventionally used as the convenient bogeyman from which central banks justify their actions. The ongoing meltdown in US Treasuries, credit markets, emerging market assets, US muni bonds, MBS, commodities and increased selling pressure on developed market stocks signifies as the convenient backdrop for the next round of rescue measures.

But if the wealth generators in the real economy has been severely damaged, and if the unfolding rout in financial asset markets will be deep enough to traumatize participants, the next wave of reflationary policies will likely spur a spike in price inflation, rather than a resumption of the speculative excess or the risk ON environment.

We may be in the next phase of the inflation cycle.

As the great dean of Austrian school of economics, Murray N. Rothbard explained[20] (bold mine)
The ultimate result of a policy of persistent inflation is runaway inflation and the total collapse of the currency. As Mises analyzed the course of runaway inflation (both before and after the first example of such a collapse in an industrialized country, in post-World War I Germany), such inflation generally proceeds as follows: At first the government's increase of the money supply and the subsequent rise in prices are regarded by the public as temporary. Since, as was true in Germany during World War I, the onset of inflation is often occasioned by the extraordinary expenses of a war, the public assumes that after the war conditions including prices will return to the preinflation norm. Hence the public's demand for cash balances rises as it awaits the anticipated lowering of prices. As a result, prices rise less than proportionately and often substantially less than the money supply, and the monetary authorities become bolder. As in the case of the Assignats during the French Revolution, here is a magical panacea for the difficulties of government: pump more money into the economy, and prices will rise only a little! Encouraged by the seeming success, the authorities apply more of what has worked so well, and the monetary inflation proceeds apace. In time, however, the public's expectations and views of the economic present and future undergo a vitally important change. They begin to see that there will be no return to the prewar norm, that the new norm is a continuing price inflation — that prices will continue to go up rather than down. Phase two of the inflationary process ensues, with a continuing fall in the demand for cash balances based on this analysis: "I'd better spend my money on X, Y, and Z now, because I know full well that next year prices will be higher." Prices begin to rise more than the increase in the supply of money. The critical turning point has arrived.
This implies that next set of central bank actions will likely undergird a transitional period from bursting bubbles to stagflation. Once stagflation becomes the order of the day the next risks will be one of runaway inflation.

Ultimately it will be the feedback loop between the actions of policymakers and markets responses to them that will shape the direction of markets.

So far, as noted above, rising interest rates appear as signs of bursting bubbles across the globe.

And global bond markets serve as our guideposts as I previously wrote[21]
What I am saying is that unless the upheavals in global bond markets stabilize, there is a huge risk of market shock that may push risk assets into bear markets.
Has the Bond Vigilantes landed on ASEAN Bond Markets?

As of the previous week, the upheaval in emerging market bonds has barely landed on the ASEAN shores, except Indonesia.

But two weeks back I warned, “the vastly narrowed Philippine-US spread may or could be an accident waiting to happen via reversion to the mean”[22]

And from last week[23]
Remember, the yield of the 10 year Philippine bonds seem to suggest that her credit risk profile has been nearly at par with Malaysia and has (astoundingly) surpassed Thailand, which for me, signifies as a bubble.

And as I have earlier pointed out, the interest rate spread between the US and Philippines has substantially narrowed. This reduces the arbitrage opportunities and thus providing incentives for foreign money to depart from local shores to look for opportunities elsewhere or perhaps take on a “home bias” position.

The EM and ASEAN bond markets are highly vulnerable to market shocks as recent events have shown.
Just looking at the IMF calculated Nominal GDP per capita[24], notably there has been a gulf in data between the Philippines US$ 2,617 on one hand, and Indonesia $3,910, Thailand $5,678 and Malaysia $10,304 on the other hand. Ironically, current bond yields which reflects on credit risks, suggests that the Philippines shares the same profile with her much ‘wealthier’ peers.

Even if the popular assumption that the Philippines will outperform her contemporaries in terms of growth over the coming years holds true (which isn’t), seen from the perspective in nominal per capita GDP, such whale of the difference indicates that Philippine bond yields seem as having been blatantly mispriced.

This may have been mainly due to recent credit rating upgrades (which will be put to test), and the rest from the credit bloated statistical growth based on easy money policy regime which is about to change.

clip_image010

Regardless of what BSP officials will say on sustaining low interest environment, if the selloff in global bonds persists, this will show up in Philippine bond yields.

10 year bond Philippine bonds yields[25] moved significantly higher during the Thursday and Friday’s stock market rout. 

Last week’s bond market actions seem as the second attempt to break beyond the 4% level. I believe that once a breakout has been attained, the upward movements will intensify.

Our neighbors have already began to show signs of distress in their bond markets…

clip_image011

Thailand and Malaysia seems to have joined Indonesia in a trajectory of ascendant yields

I don’t share the view that will entirely be a story of current accounts and external debt as some experts suggest.

Malaysia still has current account surplus but a rapidly shrinking one. Also Malaysia’s external debt has been trending lower since 2008. Yet yields of Malaysia’s 10 year bonds[26] have broken away from the highs of 2013.

Thailand recently posted a current account deficit. Thailand’s current account has been seesawing between surpluses and deficits. Thailand’s external debt has leapt by 60% since 2010. But like the Philippines, yields of Thailand’s 10 year bonds[27] appear to be making a second attempt to breach the 4% level.
Indonesia’s current account has been in a deficit since 2012, external debt has also jumped by about 40% since 2010.

So based on relative external conditions Indonesia has borne the initial brunt of a bond market[28] selloff. But the pressures on the ASEAN bond market appear to be spreading. Indonesia recently raised interest rates, but likewise announced her version of QE.

At the end of the day, sustained tightening of money conditions will not only expose on external fragilities but likewise internal imbalances or domestic bubbles. The recognition of the unsustainability of domestic assets bubbles may further incentivize liquidations already triggered by continuing collapse of the global bond markets. 

clip_image012

So far actions in the bond markets has had variable effects on equities. The above shows of the variable stock market losses since the close of the week in May 31st.

This may be due to many factors such as capital regulations, degree of foreign ownership and etc…

clip_image013

Finally while ASEAN financial assets reveals of mixed degrees of selling pressure, what has converged so far has been a sharp selloff in domestic currencies.

Yet part of the currency selloffs has been cushioned by central bank actions. For instance last week, the BSP was reported to have stepped in via open market operations to “stem the decline and smooth out the volatility”[29]

It would be interesting to see how all these selling will affect the region’s vaunted Gross International Reserves.

Will there be enough reserves to shield a sustained stream of outflows? Or will domestic central banks sharply raise rates?

Global Bond Markets Determines the Fate Of Asset Markets

Bottom line: Markets will remain highly volatile, however as previously noted, volatility will go on both direction but with a downside bias, unless again, global bond markets are pacified.

Unsettled global bond markets will continue to hound financial markets.

Emerging market outflows reached $19 billion during the past three weeks the most since 2011. This may be part of the “reversal of the $3.9 trillion of cash that flowed into emerging markets the past four years” according to a report from Bloomberg[30].

Such claim will ultimately depend on the conditions of the bond markets.

Crashing markets means that losses will continue to mount and begin to affect balance sheets of major institutions around the world.

For instance, China’s PBoC reversed course from attempting to ferret out shadow banks and reportedly infused money to a financial institution[31] as rumors floated that one of the largest commercial bank in China, the Bank of China defaulted. The latter denied such allegations[32].

Eventually smoke will likely become fire.

On the other hand, a flurry of selling has prompted one of the market’s largest exchange-traded fund sponsors of municipal bond ETFs in the US to suspend share redemptions[33].

These are initial symptoms. 

Eventually too the suppression of losses will become public which increases the likelihood of contagions.

And as stated before, the reverse reflexive feedback loop from liquidations and realized losses will affect expectations and subsequently prospective actions and vice versa.

And given the multiple hotspots brought about by the unravelling global bond markets, it would not be prudent for anyone to expect an immediate resolution on these.

Even if the US Federal Reserve decides to intervene, it would take coordinated or collaborative actions by major central banks to possibly soothe the bond markets.

But again such band-aid treatment will likely have a short term effects considering that real savings may have been substantially drained and that real wealth generators of the economy have been damaged by such policies.

Highly indebted governments will also be put on spotlight. This puts to the fore the increased risks of a debt crisis from a major economy that may ripple across the world and worsen current conditions.

But media will be stuffed with rabid denials.

If you happen to read or hear of talking heads who claim that the current selloff represents a bottom, check out first if they saw this market carnage coming. Also find out if they have “skin in the game”, before believing them.

As my favorite iconoclast Nassim Taleb recently wrote[34]
predictions in socioeconomic domains do not work, but predictors are rarely harmed by their forecasts. Yet we know that people take more risks after they see a numerical prediction. The solution is to ask – and only take into account – what the predictor has done, or will do in the future.
It’s your money that is at risk, not theirs.

So do yourself a favor of doing independent research.

Trade with utmost caution.




[3] Wall Street Journal Brazil Protests Surge Despite Concession June 21, 2013



[6] See What to Expect in 2013 January 7, 2013




[10] Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Press Release June 19, 2013


[12] Frank Shostak Drowning in a Liquidity Trap? May 24, 2013

[13] Federal Bank of Cleveland Credit Easing Policy Tools



[16] Federal Reserve bank of Richmond Price Stability & Monetary Policy



[19] Wikipedia.org Path dependence

[20] Murray N. Rothbard The Austrian Theory of Money January 3, 2012









[29] Inquirer.net Markets still shaken as peso rebounds June 21 2013





[34] Nassim Nicolas Taleb More Skin in the Game in 2013 December 31, 2013 Project Syndicate