Showing posts with label consumer price inflation. Show all posts
Showing posts with label consumer price inflation. Show all posts

Wednesday, December 03, 2014

US Consumers: Statistical World versus the Real World (Survey, Black Friday Crash, Slower Cyber Monday Sales)

It’s one thing to "live" in a world of statistics (virtual reality), and it’s another to live in "reality".

image

It’s been said that US consumers have been vibrant because confidence has been “high” while inflation remains “low”. (chart from Wall Street Journal)

Well that’s what Wall Street likes to tell the public in order to justify the manic bidding up of stocks.

But again recent surveys reveal (like Philippines self-rated poverty and anecdotal accounts), that the average American consumers have been struggling. 

On the one side, the average Americans  have reportedly been buffeted by stagnant income.

On the other, inflation’s substitution and income effects have likewise burdened consumption by reducing disposable income.

As I explained before
Price increases in energy, food, rentals and transportation will effectively reduce the average resident’s disposable income as spending will be diverted to essentials. This is the income effect.

And should there be residual disposable income, rising prices may impel the average consumer to conserve resources by switching into the more affordable alternatives. This is the substitution effect.
image

Now the plight of the average US consumers

From the Wall Street Journal (bold mine)
The American middle class has absorbed a steep increase in the cost of health care and other necessities as incomes have stagnated over the past half decade, a squeeze that has forced families to cut back spending on everything from clothing to restaurants. 

Health-care spending by middle-income Americans rose 24% between 2007 and 2013, driven by an even larger rise in the cost of buying health insurance, according to a Wall Street Journal analysis of detailed consumer-spending data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics.

That hit has been accompanied by increases in spending on other necessities, including food eaten at home, rent and education, as well as the soaring cost of staying connected digitally via cellphones and home Internet service.

With income growth sluggish, discretionary spending on things like clothing and movies, live shows and amusement parks has given way…

To see how it has moved, the Journal analyzed Labor Department data on 2013 out-of-pocket spending for the middle 60% of the population by income—households earning between about $18,000 and $95,000 a year, before taxes. 

The data show they are losing ground. Overall spending for the group rose by about 2.3% over the six-year period from 2007, even as inflation totaled about 12%. At the same time, income for the group stagnated, rising less than half a percent. 

With health care and other costs rising, these consumers spent less on furniture, entertainment, clothing and even child care, the Journal analysis found.

“Part of the story is that your income growth is slowing,” said Steven Fazzari, an economist and chairman of the sociology department at Washington University in St. Louis. “They’re spending more on necessities, cutting back on other types.”
As spending on necessities increase, this includes adaption from technological changes telephone to wireless/internet…
Spending on mobile-phone service, meanwhile, has soared, rising nearly 50% since 2007, the year the iPhone came out and data plans became more commonplace…

Similarly, spending on home Internet service has soared by more than 80%. Last year, it made up about 0.8% of spending for middle income households, up from 0.4% six years earlier. Despite talk of “cord cutting,” spending on cable and satellite television is still up 24% from 2007.
...discretionary spending has either been reduced or eliminated
Spending on housing was up just 2.4%. But that masked big declines in spending on home purchases and mortgage interest, reflecting lower levels of homeownership and low interest rates. Spending on rent soared 26%, as some families lost their homes and rising demand for apartments helped push up monthly rents.

Restaurant spending fell slightly, while outlays on food eaten at home rose 12.5%.

To make up the difference, middle income Americans have cut costs where they can. Spending on event admission and fees has fallen 16.5%, while spending for a broad category that includes boats, motor-homes, cameras and party rentals has fallen 31%.

Spending on household textiles, including bath and bed linens, has fallen 26.5%. Spending on care for children and the elderly has fallen 25%…

A variety of factors can affect spending in a category. The 6.5% decline in spending on new cars and trucks, for example, likely reflects a combination of delayed car purchases as well as a shift to less expensive vehicles, or even used ones, for which spending is up 2%. Lower apparel spending—down 11.5% overall, but down 18% for women 16 years old and over—likely reflects a combination of fewer clothing purchases and a preference for less expensive clothes, as well as aggressive discounting by retailers jockeying for business.

Spending on electricity is up 11% since 2007, according to the Labor Department data.
The middle class spending squeeze has been visible in the latest 11% crash in the much ballyhooed Black Friday sales:

From the Bloomberg: (bold mine)
Even after doling out discounts on electronics and clothes, retailers struggled to entice shoppers to Black Friday sales events, putting pressure on the industry as it heads into the final weeks of the holiday season.

Spending tumbled an estimated 11 percent over the weekend from a year earlier, the Washington-based National Retail Federation said yesterday. And more than 6 million shoppers who had been expected to hit stores never showed up.

Consumers were unmoved by retailers’ aggressive discounts and longer Thanksgiving hours, raising concern that signs of recovery in recent months won’t endure. Retailers also were targeted by protesters, who called on consumers to boycott Black Friday to make a statement about police violence. Still, the NRF cast the decline in a positive light, saying it showed shoppers were confident enough to skip the initial rush for discounts…

Consumer spending fell to $50.9 billion over the past four days, down from $57.4 billion in 2013, according to the NRF. It was the second year in a row that sales declined during the post-Thanksgiving Black Friday weekend, which had long been famous for long lines and frenzied crowds…

This year, many shoppers stayed home. The NRF had predicted that 140.1 million customers would visit retailers last weekend. Instead, only 133.7 million showed up. The slow start may make it harder for retailers to hit sales targets over the next month. The NRF had predicted a 4.1 percent sales gain for November and December -- the best performance since 2011. (the latter paragraph grafted from the bloomberg article below)
Not even Cyber Monday promos helped, from another Bloomberg article
Cyber Monday sales growth is slowing as consumers embrace the convenience of online shopping, spreading out their purchases instead of being lured by one-day specials.

Internet holiday shopping rose 8.5 percent on Cyber Monday yesterday, typically the busiest day for Web shopping as people return to their desks after the U.S. Thanksgiving holiday weekend. That compares with online sales growth of 20.6 percent posted on the same day a year earlier, according to a report by International Business Machines Corp.
Record stocks backed by questionable statitics and reality has gone in different directions. One of them is wrong, which means current conditions won’t last.

Such is a splendid example of the baneful effects from the invisible Fed facilitated arbitrary confiscation and redistribution process: By a continuing process of inflation, governments can confiscate, secretly and unobserved, an important part of the wealth of their citizens. By this method they not only confiscate, but they confiscate arbitrarily; and, while the process impoverishes many, it actually enriches some. (Keynes, The Economic Consequence of Peace)

Updated to add: There is one aspect I didn't include above: it's consumer credit. 

Let me quote Austrian economist Mark Thornton at the Mises Blog (bold mine)
In aggregate American have done some minor repairs on their balance sheets. However, looking below the aggregates we find American getting less mortgage debt but even more consumer credit and credit card debt. Consumer debt peaked at almost $2.7 trillion during the Housing Bubble. This dropped back to about $2.5 trillion during the recession. However, since that lull in consumer borrowing consumer debt has expanded to $3.15 trillion. This represents a 25% increase since the recession and an all time high
If consumers have already been laboring under lackluster income growth AND higher prices of necessities, yet recent consumption has been financed by RECORD debt, then then how much more debt can consumers absorb to sustain their current spending patterns?

Interesting no?
 

Friday, November 14, 2014

Former Fed Chief Paul Volcker Chides Yellen et al.: Do we want prices to double every generation?

It’s interesting to see the revered former US Federal Reserve Paul Volcker assail at the policies adapted by his successors.

Having known for being an inflation fighter today Mr. Volcker questions on the wisdom of inflation targeting.

A 2% inflation target? Long-term, detailed forecasts of activity? Pledges to keep rates very low well into the future? For Mr. Volcker, who led the Fed from 1979 to 1987, these are all overly precise policy choices that promise more than any central bank can deliver. What’s worse, the policies that have come to define modern Fed policy can even be counterproductive, making central bank goals harder to achieve.

Mr. Volcker, 87, weighed in on monetary policy while participating at a conference held at the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia on Thursday. The former central banker occupies a hallowed place in the institution’s history, having helmed the effort that decisively killed the high inflation that boiled out of the 1970s, albeit by way of creating a sharp economic downturn. His blunt-force approach to central bank policy making stands in sharp relief to the increasingly complex web of communications and tools that have come to define the Ben Bernanke and Janet Yellen eras of central bank leadership.

Mr. Volcker, who believes the Fed’s main goal is to defend the dollar’s stability, said he doesn’t even understand why the Fed adopted a 2% target for inflation. He asked, “Do we want prices to double every generation?”

Mr. Volcker said that “any price index is an approximation of reality,” and it would be better if the Fed was “fuzzy” about what level of prices it wished to achieve. What’s more important, he said, is that “you want a situation where people generally expect prices will be stable,” and the Fed appears to have that right now.
Apparently the article's author attempts to contradict Mr. Volcker by interjecting “Fed appears to have that right now” in allusion to stable prices. 

The problem with author’s perspective, being a seeming apologist of the modern day FED, has been to cheerlead on the tunnel vision of statistically derived consumer prices. Such statistics has been assumed to reflect on objective reality even when the components reveal different degree of inflation (yes inflation’s impact to individuals are subjective as the basket of everyone’s consumption are like thumbprints, they are distinct), when statistical smoke and mirrors have been used to determine price levels, when statistics downplay prices in the real economy (e.g. food and rental) to instead rely on surveys (e.g. owner’s equivalent rent), when  purchasing power of the US dollar has been undergoing a slomo boiling of the proverbial frog (even the US government's Bureau of Labor Statistics inflation calculator exhibits this), and most importantly, the exclusion of financial assets in the evaluation or assessment of price stability.  For the consensus, consumer prices have no apparent link to financial assets.
 
Mr. Volcker likewise rebuked the FED for shaping their policies based on inaccurate forecasts:
Mr. Volcker also said the Fed’s decision to provide long-term forecasts for key economic variables is simply folly.

“The fate of the Federal Reserve can’t depend on the accuracy of the forecasts it makes two years ahead,” he said. Offering up forecasts with greater frequency and details–the Fed now does this on a quarterly basis–simply demonstrates to the public “more frequently the forecasts aren’t that accurate.” 

Fed guidance that has at points pointed to calendar-date expectations of rate increases, as well as official guidance that rates will stay very low for a long time to come, are ultimately unproductive, he said. “If you make it precise in terms of interest rates, then the market begins working against you,” and any disconnect between what the Fed promised and what it’s delivering can cause market trouble, he said.
Mr Volcker’s point: Policies based on wrong analysis and forecasts equals unintended consequences 

The Fed’s communications ambiguity came also under Mr. Volcker’s scrutiny:
Mr. Volcker also said that officials, other than the Fed leader, are talking too much these days and making it harder for the central bank leader to deliver a coherent message about the policy outlook
In sum, Mr. Volcker’s tirade can be seen in the context of the great Austrian economist F.A. Hayek’s censure of central planners: The Fatal Conceit
The curious task of economics is to demonstrate to men how little they really know about what they imagine they can design. To the naive mind that can conceive of order only as the product of deliberate arrangement, it may seem absurd that in complex conditions order, and adaptation to the unknown, can be achieved more effectively by decentralizing decisions and that a division of authority will actually extend the possibility of overall order. Yet that decentralization actually leads to more information being taken into account.

Tuesday, September 02, 2014

US Labor Day Inflation: Why Government Statistics Should NOT be Trusted

Last weekend I wrote
I am not a fan of statistics, especially growth statistics popularly known as Gross Domestic Product (GDP). Such statistics attempts to quantify people’s actions by homogenizing disparate or heterogeneous individuals into aggregates. Think of it, if I value beer and you don’t share my values, then how can such values be “aggregated”. People’s values are in essence subjective therefore non-quantifiable.

And through accounting entries, the simplification process involves the isolation of interrelated variables and the impression to its audiences of the supposed constancy of people’s actions.
The important point is that individuals have different choices shaped by values, preferences and importantly social, political, market and even environmental conditions affecting these. In short, individual choices CHANGE across time. I may want ice cream this moment, later beer and pizza. Tomorrow I may want salad, fish and juice. My friends may treat me to a steak dinner. A strong typhoon may compel me to just consume canned goods and so forth.

These changes cannot be captured by statistics.

The same applies to statistics on price inflation

Austrian economist Dr. Richard Ebeling at the EPIC Times explains why government statistics have been incompatible with reality

First the construction of the US Consumer Price Index  (CPI) [bold mine]
How do the government statisticians construct the CPI? Month-by-month, the BLS tracks the purchases of 6,100 households across the country, which are taken to be “representative” of the approximately 320 million people living in the United States. The statisticians then construct a representative “basket” of goods reflecting the relative amounts of various consumer items these 6,100 households regularly purchase based on a survey of their buying patterns. They record changes in the prices of these goods in 24,000 retail outlets out of the estimated 3.6 million retail establishments across the whole country.

And this is, then, taken to be a fair and reasonable estimate – to the decimal point! – about the cost of living and the rate of price inflation for all the people of the United States.

Due to the costs of doing detailed consumer surveys and the desire to have an unchanging benchmark for comparison, this consumer basket of goods is only significantly revised about every ten years or so.

This means that over the intervening time it is assumed that consumers continue to buy the same goods and in the same relative amounts, even though in the real world new goods come on the market, other older goods are no longer sold, the quality of many goods are improved over the years, and changes in relative prices often result in people modifying their buying patterns.
Why there is no “average”

The fact is there is no “average” American family. The individuals in each household (moms and dads, sons and daughters, and sometimes grandparents or aunts and uncles) all have their own unique tastes and preferences. This means that your household basket of goods is different in various ways from mine, and our respective baskets are different from everyone else’s.

Some of us are avid book readers, and others just relax in front of the television. There are those who spend money on regularly going to live sports events, others go out every weekend to the movies and dinner, while some save their money for an exotic vacation.

A sizable minority of Americans still smoke, while others are devoted to health foods and herbal remedies. Some of us are lucky to be “fit-as-a-fiddle,” while others unfortunately may have chronic illnesses. There are about 320 million people in the United States, and that’s how diverse are our tastes, circumstances and buying patterns.

This means that when there is price inflation those rising prices impact on each of us in different ways….

The Consumer Price Index is an artificial statistical creation from an arithmetic adding, summing and averaging of thousands of individual prices, a statistical composite that only exists in the statistician’s calculations.
Why individuals actions depart from statistics
It is the individual goods in the subcategories of goods that we the buying public actually confront and pay when we shop as individuals in the market place. It is these individual prices for the tens of thousands of actual goods and services we find and decide between when we enter the retail places of business in our daily lives. And these monetary expenses determines for each of us, as individuals and particular households, the discovered change in the cost-of-living and the degree of price inflation we each experience.

The vegetarian male who is single without children, and never buys any types of meat, has a very different type of consumer basket of goods than the married male-female couple who have meat on the table every night and shop regularly for clothes and shoes for themselves and their growing kids.

It is the diversity of our individual consumer preferences, choices and decisions about which goods and services to buy now and over time under constantly changing market conditions that determines how each of us are influenced by changes in prices, and therefore how and by what degree price inflation or price deflation may affect each of us.
And it is government’s manipulation of money supply directly (unsterilized open market operations) and indirectly (through loanable funds in the banking system) that are key determinants in the distortion of pricing system and causing imbalances in the allocation of resources across markets and the production process. This can partly be seen in the money supply growth.

image

Nevertheless, here is the US Overall CPI as of July 201
image

Here is the Core Inflation rate (ex-food and energy) over the same period

Meanwhile here is the US Labor Day inflation

From CNN (hat tip Bob Wenzel)
Hamburger 10.3%
Steak 9%
Pork Chops +10.4%
Hotdogs 6.9%
Chicken 3%
Cheese 7.1%
Beer .4%
Soda –.4%
Two worlds apart.

Saturday, July 19, 2014

Chart of the Day: Inflation's Income and Substitution Effect on American Consumer Spending

The fundamental dynamic behind price inflation would be a shift in consumer spending pattern. Without corresponding increases in income, consumer price inflation leads to the income and substitution effect.

The income effect from higher prices is to reduce or lower demand.

The substitution effect switches spending to focus on the "needs" rather than on the "wants". 

In short, consumer price inflation reduces disposable income.


As CPI builds, we see the same dynamics unfolding in US consumer spending as exhibited by the chart from Zero Hedge/Goldman Sachs

Tuesday, June 17, 2014

Street Talk: Reactions of Philippine Residents to the current surge in consumer price Inflation rates

The Wall Street Journal Interactive took a small sample of reactions by Philippine residents on the recent surge in consumer price inflation.

Very interesting comments or responses to the question by the Wall Street Journal on “How do you offset rising prices?” (bold mine)
-We cut off our family Sunday dinners in restaurants. I seldom spend on clothes, since I get these from my relatives abroad. I stopped buying accessories and pieces of jewelry. We now skip buying treats like pizza and ice cream.

-We changed our shopping habits. Before [prices rose], we would go out on pay day. Now, we stay at home during the weekends and cook two kilos of fried chicken every pay day.

-I reduce my costs by not shopping for women’s luxuries, like accessories.

-I concentrate on basic needs. Traveling is no longer a necessity but a privilege. In the 1990’s when I was studying, the jeepney fare was 1.50 pesos. Then, while I was in college, I spent 6 pesos daily. In the past, price increases were not drastic. Today, we are experiencing price fluctuations.

-Buying new clothes and accessories are costly and unnecessary. I decided to stop buying those.
Here is what I wrote last March (bold original)
Given that the Philippines has been relatively significantly less productive economy (as revealed by the huge informal economy and the lack of depth in both formal banking and capital markets) the average populace are likely to be more prone or highly sensitive to price inflation compared to her much wealthier neighbors.

Price increases in energy, food, rentals and transportation will effectively reduce the average resident’s disposable income as spending will be diverted to essentials. This is the income effect.

And should there be residual disposable income, rising prices may impel the average consumer to conserve resources by switching into the more affordable alternatives. This is the substitution effect.

Sustained price pressures on basic goods would imply that the forces of the income and the substitution effects will increasingly come into play.
The above is a basic demonstration of rising consumer price inflation's impact on demand via the income effect (reduced or stop buying...) and the substitution effect (changed shopping habits...stay at home) in motion. 

Soaring property prices combined with accelerating consumer price inflation in food that has spread to a broader base of consumer and even to producers goods (e.g. cement as shown signs of increase in black market activities) will serve as a lethal cocktail mix to the "this time is different" credit financed boom. The adverse impact will not only affect demand but likewise negatively impact incomes (jobs), earnings (profits) and eventually asset valuations.

The same forces will expose on the myth of the supposed "transformational" Philippine consumer economy which has underpinned the Shopping mall bubble.

Friday, June 13, 2014

Watch Out, Surging Oil Prices will COMPOUND on Inflation Risks!

Low-flation eh?

From Reuters:
Oil prices jumped to nine-month highs on Thursday, as concerns mounted that escalating violence in Iraq could disrupt oil supplies from the second-largest OPEC producer.

Sunni Islamist militants, who took over Iraq's second-biggest city Mosul earlier this week, extended their advance south toward Baghdad and surrounded the country's largest refinery in the northern town of Baiji on Thursday.
Let us see these via charts.

image

The US crude benchmark the WTIC just had a breakout!

image

US gasoline likewise posted a seeming breakout, which will likely be confirmed or falsified during the coming sessions.

This will ADD to the growing inflation pressures in the US which will jeopardize the stock market bubble.

image

Even Europe's Brent Crude seems as testing a critical resistance level.

The question is will troubles in Iraq signify a temporary event or will these escalate?

The recent twist of events reveals how the US Bush-Obama war on Iraq has not only been a dramatic failure of US interventionist policies, but a blowback, as the so-called terrorists seemingly beating back the Americans at their own game.  Talk about Karma.

These also seem as the unintended consequence of the confused and self contradictory imperial policies by the US government in the region.

Paradoxically, the client state or the US sponsored Iraq government has been fighting off insurgents whom has relations with US backed rebels in Syria!

From the PBS Frontline (May 2014): The interviews are the latest evidence that after more than three years of warfare, the United States has stepped up the provision of lethal aid to the rebels. In recent months, at least five rebel units have posted videos showing their members firing U.S.-made TOW anti-tank missiles at Syrian positions…many both inside and out of government fear U.S.-provided weapons could make their way into extremist hands, particularly in a place like Syria, where alliances and foes change with breakneck fluidity. Moderate rebel groups have worked closely with the al Qaida-aligned Nusra Front and the Islamic Front, one of whose factions, Ahrar al Sham, includes al Qaida members among its founders."

Now Iraq’s rebels could be using some of the US provided weapons in their war to take control of Iraq via Baghdad. 

Al Qaida-inspired militants from ISIS, the Islamic State of Iraq and al-Sham, have reportedly seized US Black Hawk helicopters, looted 500 billion Iraqi dinars - the equivalent of $429m (£256m) - from Mosul's central bank, has now laid siege or surrounded Iraq's largest refinery in Baiji, and may have unleashed a sectarian war.

Reports the Zero Hedge: As the WSJ reports, after hard core Al Qaeda spin off ISIS (no relation to Sterling Archer) took over Saddam's home town of Tikrit yesterday, Iraq edged closer to all-out sectarian conflict on Thursday as Kurdish forces took control of a provincial capital in the oil-rich north and Sunni militants vowed to march on two cities revered by Shiite Muslims.  Kurdish militia known as peshmerga said they had taken up positions in key government installations in Kirkuk, as forces of the Shiite-dominated government of Prime Minister Nouri al-Maliki abandoned their posts and fled in fear of advancing Sunni militants, an official in the office of the provincial governor said.

Cumulative years of US interventions seem to have triggered a regional conflagration.

Yet the US government will continue to intervene as wars signifies as good business for the politically influential military industrial complex. President Obama has pledged to support the incumbent Iraq government, but did not offer ground troops.

Aside from the renewed outbreak violence in Iraq, one ramification of the US –Russia proxy civil war in Ukraine has been a test of mettle between two major military powers: The US government acknowledged that they have scrambled jet fighters to intercept 4 Russian bombers who flew nearly 50 miles off the California Coast. Wow! Russians frontally testing the US.

As geopolitical risks have been simmering, the effects of which has been to disrupt supply chains (as oil), thereby compounding on pressures to global consumer price inflation.

But for the don’t worry be happy crowd, whether in the Philippines or the US or elsewhere, various additional risks aside from inflation, such as protectionism or war should be dismissed because stocks are bound to rise forever, based on the kooky idea of "don't fight the FED" or central banks! Maybe they think that central banks can print oil too.

Wednesday, June 11, 2014

Harvard’s Martin Feldstein warns US Inflation Is Running Above 2%

Inflation is a process which represents political actions that comes with economic consequences. And because money and credit creation operates in stages, this impacts relative sectors (first recipient of money) with relative price changes that eventually spreads through the system. In other words, since inflation is a process, they don’t just happen as the mainstream sees them. And they are hardly about just supply side problems.

In the US, inflationary pressures seen via the consumer price index has been inching higher. Some experts have seen this as approaching danger zone.

At the Wall Street Journal Harvard professor and former chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers under President Ronald Reagan Martin Feldstein warns of a possible surge in US inflation (bold mine)
Inflation is rising in the United States and could become a serious problem sooner than the Federal Reserve and many others now recognize. There are three basic reasons why the Fed is too optimistic in its current forecast that inflation will remain below its 2% target until after 2016.

First, data indicate that prices are already rising faster than 2% and have accelerated in recent months. Second, the low rate of short-term unemployment may be creating pressure for faster inflation despite the large total number of unemployed and underemployed individuals. And third, the rhetoric of Fed officials indicates that the central bank may not react quickly and aggressively enough if inflation continues to rise above 2%

image

This is the current conditions of US inflation as seen via PCE and CPI, charts from Doug Short

For the possible lagging effects on employment, let us tune back to Professor Feldstein

Will unemployment limit wage inflation? The unemployment rate is still a relatively high 6.3%, but an unusually large one-third of those who are counted as unemployed have been out of work for more than six months. Because the long-term unemployed are less connected with the active job market, they may provide less downward pressure on wage inflation. Recent research by Princeton's Alan Krueger and two of his colleagues indicates that wages respond to the number of short-term unemployed rather than to the total unemployment rate.

More specifically, the Brookings Institution study written with Mr. Krueger's Princeton colleagues Judd Cramer and David Cho implies that the unemployed who have been out of work for six months or more do not affect wage inflation. In contrast, wages begin to rise more rapidly when the unemployment rate among those out for less than six months declines to between 4% and 4.5%. Since the unemployment rate of those out for less than six months was only 4.1% in May, wages may soon begin to rise more rapidly.

Not everyone is convinced by this research. A more recent study by a Federal Reserve staff member suggests that the difference between the inflation effects of the long-term and short-term unemployed may only reflect recent experience and not be a good guide to the future. And William Dudley, president of the New York Fed, argues that the distinction between the effects of short-term and long-term unemployment depends on whether the long-term unemployment is cyclical or reflects structural and demographic changes that will limit their return to work even as markets tighten.

Is the Krueger research an accurate warning that labor markets are now closer to the threshold at which inflation begins to rise despite the substantial total number of people who aren't working? By the time we do know if he's right, it may be much more difficult to contain inflationary pressures.
I would add that wage inflation can already be seen via increases in minimum wages in several states.
 
-38 states have considered minimum wage bills during the 2014 session; 34 states are considering increases to the state minimum wage.

-Connecticut, Delaware, Hawaii, Maryland, Michigan, MinnesotaVermont, West Virginia and D.C. have enacted increases so far in 2014.
What do all these imply? Well this should mean higher interest rates.
image

Yields of 10 year US notes appear to have partly been reflecting this.

The other implication is that since current US stock market record boom has been financed by deepening leverage, then higher rates will jeopardize the boom.

But don’t worry be happy, the ECB recently joined the bandwagon to produce inflation. So while this may in transient boost stocks, this will also COMPOUND on the growing inflation risks

And not only the ECB, a  newly published working paper by the IMF recommends more inflation to partly solve the debt problem
This paper investigates the impact of low or high inflation on the public debt-to-GDP ratio in the G-7 countries. Our simulations suggest that if inflation were to fall to zero for five years, the average net debt-to-GDP ratio would increase by about 5 percentage points over the next five years. In contrast, raising inflation to 6 percent for the next five years would reduce the  average net debt-to-GDP ratio by about 11 percentage points under the full Fisher effect and about 14 percentage points under the partial Fisher effect. Thus higher inflation could help reduce the public debt-to-GDP ratio somewhat in advanced economies. However, it could hardly solve the debt problem on its own and would raise significant challenges and risks. First of all, it may be difficult to create higher inflation, as evidenced by Japan’s experience  in the last few decades. In addition, un-anchoring of inflation expectations could increase long-term real interest rates, distort resource allocation, reduce economic growth, and hurt the lower–income households.
Inflation has always been seen as a magic wand by the government and by statists. 

They hardly consider the real socio-economic problems associated and or brought about by inflation. Venezuela should be a wonderful example.

Oh yes, please be reminded of the evils of inflation, again from chief inflation proponent John Maynard Keynes
Lenin is said to have declared that the best way to destroy the capitalist system was to debauch the currency. By a continuing process of inflation, governments can confiscate, secretly and unobserved, an important part of the wealth of their citizens. By this method they not only confiscate, but they confiscate arbitrarily; and, while the process impoverishes many, it actually enriches some.
The unintended consequences of all these quasi permanent boom policies will emerge in due time...soon.

Monday, June 09, 2014

Phisix: 30+% Money Supply Growth Rate Now Seen in Official CPI Data

A person of free intelligence who writes openly and without fear, and is generously angry with the prevailing falsehoods of the day. – Professor Peter Boettke

In this issue:

Phisix: 30+% Money Supply Growth Rate Now Seen in Official CPI Data
-Philippines’ Subsidy Politics: The Steady March to a Rice (Food) Crisis
-Why Rice Smuggling will Persists: Clue (politicians depend on them)
-30+% Money Supply Growth Rate Now Seen in Official CPI Data
-More on the Divergence Between Money Supply and Bank Loan Growth
-Philippine Hyped Economic Growth Story: Beware the Mean Reversion
-Bingo! BPO Growth Rates Tumbles Big
-Phisix: More Marking the Close, Manic Punts Amidst Slowing Volume
-The ECB Takes the ‘Euthanasia of the Rentier’ to Reality

Phisix: 30+% Money Supply Growth Rate Now Seen in Official CPI Data

My rice supplier increased prices of a sinandomeng 25 kg sack by another 4.16% this week. This marks the second price hike this year, the last time was just almost a month ago! This would also be the third increase in about a year.

Philippines’ Subsidy Politics: The Steady March to a Rice (Food) Crisis

My personal rice inflation experience seems consistent with recent national developments. Reports say that between January and April, “rice prices rose by 27 percent for regular milled variety in Metro Manila, vis-à-vis national average increase of 18 percent for the well-milled variety[1]”. Such developments have partly been imputed to global dynamics, as well as, to domestic factors supposedly due to ‘low inventories’ and high domestic energy prices.

Meanwhile, a government economic research agency, the Philippine Institute for Development Studies (PIDS), noted that in 2013, milled rice increased spiked by 15% which they associate with “a decline in official rice imports” and not from “price manipulation by rice cartels.[2]” The agency attributes the deluge of “unofficial imports reached around one million tons” to the price arbitrage between local and global prices. Global rice prices as measured by the Oryza White Rice Index or “weighted average of global white rice export quote” grew by 5% last year.

Since 2009, unofficial imports has been estimated by domestic authorities at “80 million sacks or four million metric tons (MT)” with an estimated worth of P56 billion[3]

The Philippine government has been slated to import 800,000 metric tons from Vietnam this year, following last April’s bidding which was won by the government of Vietnam. Unfortunately some of Vietnam’s private exporters have officially been refusing to deliver rice supplies noting that “prices are too low to cover their expenses[4]”. They have announced plans to renegotiate with the National Food Authority (NFA).

As usual, both the government and mainstream media trace the unfolding events in the rice markets to superficial supply chain problems. Here, the PIDS fails to explain why the domestic prices have been ‘high’ from which incentivizes arbitraging that led to rampant rice smuggling. High domestic prices are products of underlying market, legal and institutional conditions. High prices don’t just occur for hardly any reason at all.

Let us dive into the economic picture.

From the demand side, whatever happened to the BSP’s aggregate domestic demand boosting policies? Whatever happened to all those cumulative expansion of banking credit loans which represents fresh spending power or injected demand that has been ventilated as 30+% money supply growth rates? How did the additional massive purchasing power influence rice and food prices? By shoring up a credit boom via new money flowing into the economic streams, how has these not led to increased consumption in terms of food?

How is it that when it comes to the dark side of the credit financed boom, demand suddenly exists in a vacuum?

How about the added demand derived from prices set artificially, not by the markets, but by political forces? How much of demand comes from such subsidies?

True, such subsidies have been meant to support the underprivilege, but at what costs? Are the underprivledged really benefiting from the policies?

And on the supply side, whatever happened also to the entrenched protectionist policies long embraced by the Philippine government? Won’t these raise internal costs of rice production? Whatever happened to all those subsidies thrown by the national government to the NFA?

Time to dig down into the details.

The agricultural industry has been benighted by both non-tariffs (e.g. quantitative restrictions) and tariffs barriers. For instance, high tariffs on onions, potatoes, garlic and cabbages have prompted for a proliferation of smuggling.

While the previous regime has partly opened rice importations to the private sector, instead of import quotas being awarded to the highest bidder, quotas has been granted to “choices” by the NFA authorities and by the national government. In other words, the outcome of the politicization of the distribution of quotas has been to reward “parties close to the agency or to the government in power”, according to local economist, professor and former National Economic Development Authority (NEDA) Director Gerardo Sicat[5].

Yet the same parties transform these quotas into “quick profits” by selling these to importers. Meanwhile, the failure by the government to collect the duties on rice imports from these importers becomes part of the unofficial imports.

So the government created their own predicament. First, they put up a high barrier against access to low priced agricultural products abroad. This has been intended to supposedly protect domestic farmers but comes at the expense of the Filipino consumer. Second, the government promotes inefficiency that raises cost of production and thereby reflecting on market prices. And third, they provide legal loopholes from which government and their cronies take advantage of or profit from.

But the buck doesn’t stop here.

The public choice dimension comes into play.

The politicization of the rice and agricultural markets has become a milking cow meant as “a convenient tool for public distribution of commodities” used to win electoral votes for incumbent politicians, wrote the former undersecretary of the Department of Agriculture Bruce Tolentino in a 2008 Wall Street Journal article[6]. He gives an example where “In 2006, the Senate Blue Ribbon Committee and the Committee on Agriculture and Food released a report that stated that in 2004, proceeds arising from fertilizer procurement and distribution helped finance the election campaign of President Gloria Macapagal Arroyo.”

And the use of the NFA machinery for vote buying has not just been limited to top officials, but has been pervasive even from politicians at the local levels.

Yet the essence of cost of rice protectionism, Mr. Tolentino notes, has been the unintended consequence or the opposite the goals from which the whole institution has been established. (bold mine)
Not so in Manila, where succeeding presidents and NFA administrators have defended the NFA as necessary to shield rice farmers from low world prices and ensure stable supplies for consumers. Unfortunately, this policy has had exactly the opposite effect: The incomes of the Philippines's rice farmers have consistently ranked in the lowest quintile of the population, and domestic consumer rice prices are roughly double world prices. Worse, the NFA is now one of the largest drains on the nation's already precarious fiscal resources, requiring an annual subsidy of at least 1.2 billion Philippine pesos ($29 million) from national coffers, not to mention uncollected tariffs and opportunity losses due to price premiums borne by Filipino consumers.
In short, noble sounding but economically unviable programs have been used by politicians as cover to fulfill self-serving agenda. 

So structural deficiencies in both the supply and demand side from the excessive politicization of the industry have, thus, resulted to HIGH domestic prices of rice.

Yet here is an update on the annual NFA subsidies and debts.

From the Philippine President’s Speech at the Congress on the 2013 budget[7]: This Administration will allot P7.4 billion for our banner rice program, while P1.5 billion and P1.75 billion will go to our corn and coconut development programs, respectively. Meanwhile, the Bureau of Fisheries and Aquatic Resources will receive P4.6 billion, a sizeable increase from the P3.0-billion budget given them in 2012.

On NFA’s ballooning debt, from the Manila Standard[8] (bold mine): In the last year of the Arroyo administration, the NFA’s debt stood at P177.6 billion. In the first two years of the Aquino administration, the debts declined to P148 billion because it chose to tap the private sector, which shelled out the money for importation. As of December 2013, the NFA debt has ballooned to P173 billion. With this new 1 million metric tons at an estimated P20 billion, the NFA debt will surpass Arroyo’s record because the debt would soar to P197.6 billion,” the member, who sits also in the Economic Cabinet Cluster, told the Council.

Yet despite the increase in subsidies, the NFA continues to bleed. Accrued financial losses have reached Php 5.8 billion as of June 20, 2013. And because of insufficient funding for the subsidies, the NFA has resorted to borrowing money from the marketplace. The NFA’s capital deficiency has rapidly ballooned by nearly double from Php 75 billion to Php 143.75 billion says an NFA official[9].

In case you haven’t you noticed, on the surface, despite instituted political controls, rice prices have partly been adjusting to reflect on market conditions. But the symptoms of dislocations from the miscellany of political interventions (demand and supply side) have been surfacing via increased supply side strains compounded with the growing financial pressures on the government.

In addition, the above demonstrates of the subsidy nature that undergirds Philippine politics. However this comes in the context of the contributions by the heavily politicized agricultural industry, particularly, subsidies on demand as provided for by politically suppressed (agricultural) prices, subsidies on demand from the BSP’s inflationary boom, taxpayer and peso holder support to an intensely bloated bureaucracy, resource transfers to cronies channeled through arbitrarily determined rice import quotas, tacit backing to the political ambitions of incumbent politicians through the use of government (NFA) resources, and finally aid to the NFA’s debt build up via zero bound rates or financial repression policies.

This means that the current development in agricultural politics points to four scenarios: greater credit risks via intensifying debt accumulation, higher taxes, sustained increases in consumer price inflation (yes more rice inflation) or a mélange of the three.

All these are manifestations that the current system is UNSUSTAINABLE and will eventually breakdown in the fullness of time.

At the end of the day, unless the Philippine government allows the law of economics to work by liberalizing the agricultural-rice markets through the dismantling of legal protectionist barriers, Philippine residents should expect HIGHER rice and food inflation overtime and or BIGGER public debts.

So while there has been little apprehensions over rice supplies over the interim, such ballooning imbalances brought about by a jungle of interventionist policies, heightens the risks of not only a financial crisis but a FOOD crisis through the passage of time. Unfortunately these have largely been unnoticed by the public whom have been blindsided by the phony boom and by the bread and circuses populist politics.

In short, political choices encompassing the agricultural industry will postulate to a tradeoff between current short term populist convenience (mostly in favor of politicians and their cronies) and a sustainable and functioning system. But since politician’s hold on power is short term, so will be the responses.

Why Rice Smuggling will Persists: Clue (politicians depend on them)

And contrary to the popular perception that unofficial imports or smuggling is ‘evil’, the public fails to realize that smuggling represents a NATURAL market response to a repressive political-economic environment. Smuggling is part of the informal economy.

Imagine if estimates are correct where rice smuggled into the Philippines has totaled some 1 million tons a year since 2009, then this means smuggling has not only ADDED to supply but has also HELPED in containing rice price inflation!

Here are some back of the envelop numbers for rice economics in the Philippines.

The Philippines has reportedly achieved 97% rice ‘self-sufficiency’[10] where the gap between the demand and supply is what imports (official and unofficial) have been all about. The government imported 700,000 MT in 2013. For 2014, the programmed imports have been at 1.2 million MT where the earlier tranche of 400,000 MT has been tendered last December[11] and probably already shipped in. The balance of 800,000 MT represents the Vietnam project. The additional imports may be partly due to the aftermath of Typhoon Yolanda.

Thus rice smuggling competes with the official imports and or should serve as an excess or surplus buffer. In both ways, rice smuggling should help bring down rice prices. But rice prices have been increasing!

image

Despite the rhetoric of self-sufficiency, the Philippine government has either severely miscalculated on the economic balance of rice, and or, that such political programs has translated to massive ‘inefficiency’ where in both cases rice prices continue to spike. Yes production has increased alright but these came at a severe cost to the public as expressed in prices, these in spite of price controls!

As one would note from the above charts[12], instead of achieving either affordable rice prices and or to secure public security from the political programs of rice self-sufficiency, the inflation of rice prices has persisted over the long run, if not having to accelerate over the latter pre-Aquino administration years.

This so-called self-sufficiency political program has been a legacy from the tyrannical Marcos regime called ‘Masagana 99’[13], which has been carried over by different administrations since its inception.

Alternatively, we can deduce that without smuggling, perhaps the Philippines MAY have already realized a RICE/Food crisis. Rice smuggling, in short, helps politicians BUY time from the current unfeasible rice political economic regime.

Or might I propound a radical viewpoint: Rice smuggling signifies a veiled subsidy to politicians in terms of prolonging their tenure through the attainment of temporary social stability. The implication of which is that all these media based political clampdown on rice smuggling represents only entertainment value and or another publicity shtick designed to show the squeaky clean image of the incumbent government for the latter to attain their personal political goals. In reality, the incumbent government, as with their predecessors, depends on rice smuggling to make up for, and or to act as insurance against, their policy calculation errors and to keep public security intact. So despite all the demagoguery and media hysteria about political correctness, we should expect rice smuggling to persist.

Finally it’s also important to note that the reactions to higher domestic costs of rice production by Vietnamese farmers in resisting to deliver rice supplies to the NFA reveals of the disruptive effects of the current global inflation process in motion. 

And more importantly, the self-inflicted obstacles in the industry also expose on the depth of sensitivity or vulnerability of the domestic food supply chain to exogenous factors, especially to an outbreak of global protectionism.
Fish see the bait, but not the hook; men see the profit, but not the peril. - Chinese Proverb
30+% Money Supply Growth Rate Now Seen in Official CPI Data

The rice inflation predicament has been more than just my personal suffering.

Today, this plays a significant role in the BSP’s current admission of a surge in consumer price inflation rates.

Philippine price inflation notes the Wall Street Journal “rose to its quickest pace since November 2011”. But “don’t worry be happy”, because this has supposedly been within the Philippine central bank, the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas’ ambit, “CPI remains within the bank’s 3.0%-5.0% target range”[14]

You see central banks are never wrong. Since they make the statistics, they declare or impose on the public the reality which they desire to show. For instance in Argentina, the ‘decreed’ official inflation rate is at 10.98%, but despite the January rate hikes[15], annual implied inflation rates (as measured by Cato’s Troubled Currency Project) has zoomed back to now 38%! I say ‘decreed’ because local economists have been banned from saying otherwise.

Now the 4.5% inflation based on the BSP’s official statement[16] (bold mine): The continued uptick of headline inflation in May was attributed largely to higher food prices and electricity charges. Tight domestic supply conditions led to higher prices of key food items, particularly rice, meat, fish, milk, oils, and sugar. At the same time, higher spoilage during the summer season adversely affected domestic supply in the case of fruits and vegetables. Meanwhile, the increase in electricity rates as a result of higher generation charges in areas outside National Capital Region also contributed to the rise in non-food inflation.
Curiously again, the inflation problem swings to the supply side where demand, particularly demand based on credit inflation, has vaporized. Yet there has been no explanation what has caused the “tight domestic supply conditions”.

If you look at the BSP’s inflation details which I urge to do, you will notice that the inflation components have been broken down into 3 major categories: Food and Non-Alcoholic beverage (with a 38.98% weight), Alcoholic beverage and Tobacco (2% weight) and the biggest NON-Food items (constituting 58.99% weight).

The biggest member for Food grouping has been bread and cereals which accounts for 12.44% of total CPI index, from which the largest subclass has been rice at 8.92% share, again of the total CPI basket. [To emphasize, the statistics I mention here are weights relative to the BSP’s overall CPI model]

For the non-Food category, housing constitutes the largest share at 22.47% weight, with ‘actual rentals’ as a sub-category at 13.75% of the CPI basket. 

Interestingly, if not surprisingly, a second biggest component in the non-Food segment has been ‘Restaurants and Miscellaneous Goods and Services’ with a 12.03% share. Catering services, which represent the biggest share of the said group accounts for 8.01% of the overall CPI pie.

I say “surprisingly”, because I never realized of the significance of the eating habits of the average residents would capture an influential share of the BSP’s inflation pie. The implication from the above goes like this: The average residents prefer to eat out or to have food catered at home even with their limited purchasing power. This is something that I will NEVER logically comprehend.

And given that the Restaurants (the means of selling food) are related to the Food index, then combined (catering services + Food index- non-alcoholic beverages) would amount to 44.3% share of BSP’s CPI model. If this represents the share of a household budget, then this statistics don’t fit mine. I am quite confident this won’t suit up to the lifestyles of many or if not a majority.

Let me further add, rice in a typical meal (one viand one cup of rice) at the informal food outlet would likely account for 20% of the total expenditure by a customer. In my personal observation, young male consumers of the informal economy food outlet tend to have more rice than viand. So the share of rice consumed per meal could be higher.

So even from the methodological construct perspective of the CPI basket alone, there seems little representativeness of the inflation data to the real world.

Yet rice inflation in the perspective of the BSP report—based on May—says 12.9% (year-on-year), 1% (month-on-month) and 11.5% January to April. The latter data greatly departs from the news I cited above where “national average increase of 18 percent for the well-milled variety”. That’s about 6.5% differentials!

Also the BSP notes of “higher prices of key food items, particularly rice, meat, fish, milk, oils, and sugar”. Unfortunately the BSP didn’t say that these are exactly areas covered by the Price Act (REPUBLIC ACT NO. 7581[17]). This means that these items have been monitored, regulated or under selective price controls by the government. This also means market price flexibility has been taken off the table. So instead of posting (black) market prices, the BSP will likely indicate the “regulated’ prices in their report. So the most likely ramification is that price inflation have been much HIGHER than indicated by the BSP’s report!

Another MORE interesting data is the housing segment called ‘actual rents’ which has a share of 13.75% of the CPI basket. The BSP rent data as of May registered 1.8% (y-o-y), .4% (m-o-m) and 1.7% (January to April). These figures don’t seem to fit with the property boom story!

I can only make anecdotal comparisons based on media’s report.

Based on office rentals (differentiated by grade and location), in 2014 the industry expects rental prices to advance by anywhere 4.4% to 8.2%. Supposedly due to ‘tight vacancy rates’, some developers will even be offering pre-leasing contracts.

For the low cost housing, the government has extended rent controls for 2 more years. The rent control policy limits annual rental prices increases to 7% for as long as these apply to same tenant occupied units[18]. The rent control covers units with rental prices below 10,000 pesos in the National Capital Region (NCR) and other urban areas. In the rural areas, the populist edict applies to rental units of 5,000 pesos and below.

As a side note, since rent controls preclude property owners from adjusting prices based on market realities (which essentially violates property rights of property owners), the economic outcome will be one of shortages in housing supply for these housing categories as depressed prices reduce the incentive to provide additional supplies. Another negative from rent control policies is the deterioration in the quality of rent spaces, which not only lead to the dilapidation or loss of worth the housing values, but importantly raises the specter of various housing risk hazards. For instance, why would a property owner spend to improve on his property’s safety when his income does not permit so?

Yet the consequent shortages of housing supply become part of the demand for ‘socialized housing’. So the problems (shortages) created by earlier interventions (rent control) result to more interventions (socialized housing). And as I previously noted[19] socialized housing contributes to the current housing bubble. So two wrongs make no right.

Of course, these would be pronounced, if rental control programs are strictly enforced.

Nonetheless even the minimum allowable price increases on the low cost housing rent reveals that the BSP’s data has been out of line with real developments.

Again as previously pointed out, even BSP officials know or admit that their inflation data are hardly an accurate representation of reality. Here is a reprise of a quote from BSP Deputy Governor Diwa C Guinigundo’s paper published at the Bank of international Settlements[20] (bold mine)
Excluding asset price components from headline inflation also has little effect. Currently, the CPI includes only rent and minor repairs. The rent component of the CPI is, however, not reflective of the market price because of rent control legislation. The absence of a real estate price index (REPI) reflects valuation problems, owing largely to the institutional gaps in property valuation and taxation. While the price deflator derived from the gross value added from ownership of dwellings and real estate could represent real property price, it is also subject to frequent revisions, making it difficult to forecast inflation.
To repeat: Not REFLECTIVE of the market price because of rent control legislation, see what I mean?

Notice too in the BSP annualized CPI inflation figures for May 2014, only 2 sectors posted negative growth, specifically, Transport services (-.1%) and telephone and telefax equipment (-.7%)—the latter seems as sign of obsolescence, whereas significant categories in the BSP model have registered growth numbers north of 2%.

You see, the nasty side effects of the 30+% money supply growth rate have now become more visible as I have repeatedly been warning about here.

Four implications from these:

1) Higher input prices will CRIMP or COMPRESS on corporate profits.
2) Rising CPI means a redistribution of expenditures by households which would mean DIMINISHED disposable income, thereby constricting demand.
3) Higher inflation rates will also mean HIGHER interest rates which again will add to the pressures of servicing debt. This will compound on the strains on profit margins, as well as, increase credit risks for highly leveraged entities. Higher debt service will also REDUCE the incentive to expand capital expenditures which also squeezes demand.
4) The last but most important would be the repercussions from these three dynamics: That the aggregate demand policies of credit expansion that has fueled economic and financial speculation aimed at attaining a “quasi-permanent boom” may now be in jeopardy.

I may add to this the predicament that annualized money supply growth rate continues to plateau in April despite the banking system’s unshakeable credit annualized 18.9% growth over the same period. The most likely factor for this new ‘contrasting’ development where fresh injected money hasn’t been generating additional demand or “traction” is that the current surge in borrowed money are being used to pay off or service existing debt[21]. In short, a possible increase in the use of debt in debt out or Ponzi financing.

As a side note, it has even been possible that the initial toll from all these has resulted to a drop in the 1st quarter GDP growth rate to 5.7% from the former 6-7% levels, which went against the consensus expectations. This ‘surprising’ slowdown has been blamed by the government on Typhoon Yolanda as a ‘one-off’ or anomalous event which popular opinion swallowed hook, line and sinker. Yet ironically, the only direct connection between the lackluster GDP performance in the 1Q 2014 and Typhoon Yolanda has been in the coconut industry![22] A secondary factor has been pinned to the supposed tightening by the BSP. But as I have pointed above, an increase in general banking loans growth rate of 18.9% in April from 18.1% in March (y-o-y) represents some tightening eh?

More on the Divergence Between Money Supply and Bank Loan Growth

Back to the growing divergence between money supply-loan growth performance; yet if my suspicion is anywhere accurate, then this indicates that highly leveraged firms or institutions may have reached their “saturation” levels in terms of debt absorption. The diminishing law of returns of debt relative to output means that more debt is required to produce a unit output. But of course, there are limits to such debt financed debt rollover which squarely depends on low interest rates and the burden from the level of debt itself. Since debt is used to pay for existing debt, then this means mounting debt burdens.

If existing highly levered companies can’t produce growth from every marginal new debt acquired, then either the government will have to make up for the slack, or the banking system would need to attract more participants to borrow to cover up on the deficiency.

However, none of the prospective gap filling measures to juice up the statistical economy removes the aspect of rising risks from a potential disorderly unwind from highly leveraged companies. Yet the seeming increasing use of debt IN-debt OUT (Ponzi financing) operations by more firms only highlights on the intensifying degree of the vulnerability and sensitivity to interest rate adjustments that has been building up on the system.

And because of the limited penetration level of the banking system, this won’t be obvious in general debt data. But this will be apparent on a per company basis.

[As a side note, bubble worshipers always love to keep using debt data of other nations to compare with the Philippines and declare a free pass on current debt conditions. Again these are apples to oranges comparison, primarily because of the many structural distinctions such as bank penetration level, legal institutions, size of markets, culture and etc…. They should rather look at the data during the 1997 Asian Crisis and see how despite low levels, the crisis buffeted the Philippines. And as I previously wrote[23], debt tolerance level differs from country to country as seen when a crisis hit. Even during the onset of the Asian crisis, statistical figures like bank lending to the property sector, property exposure and non-performing loans or even vacancy rates had all been different for ASEAN nations. The Philippines has generally the “lowest” among all these variables. Paradoxically lowest does NOT translate to immunity.]

There are already pressures being applied on the BSP to raise rates such as the HSBC.

But considering how the government has been acutely hooked to the stimulus, I have reservations if the BSP will submit to such pressures.

The BSP appears to have pulled the proverbial “wool over the eyes” of the markets by recently raising reserve requirements twice. They further claim their raising of reserve requirements have allegedly “siphoned some $2.7 billion from the system”[24]. Yet banking loans growth in April increased by Php 556.318 billion (nominal, y-o-y). At USD-peso of 43.5 this would mean an increase of US $ 12.789 billion. So I really don’t know where such siphoning took place. They can’t blame it on liquidity because liquidity has been slowing since January even before the reserve requirement changes.

Also, according to modern central bank operations, reserves are today “supplied” by the central banks, rather than the banking system adjusting to the changes in mandated reserves. This basically means that reserves don’t serve as a constraint to bank lending, unless the BSP operates in an archaic system.

The BSP, like the supposed reserve requirement tool or like the flagrant disregard of their self-imposed 20% banking loan cap to the real estate industry, will likely use policy tool “stunts” or smokescreens to sustain the status quo which essentially neglects the risks being amassed in the system.

Yet even if the BSP does raise rates, which will likely be minimal, I expect an initial jump in the demand for loans as the market will likely race to lock in loans at short term rates.

Nevertheless, it will be interesting to see how the government and the BSP whom has been applying self-contradictory measures, on the one hand, price inflation suppression through the massaging of financial markets, statistical camouflages, publicity flimflam and even price controls in the real economy, while on the other hand, encouraging (or doing little to control or stem) a bank lending based boom. Yet these two forces are incompatible. One of them will be exposed for their artificiality…soon

Philippine Hyped Economic Growth Story: Beware the Mean Reversion

Let me add to my act as the unpopular spoiler of this boom.

In near unanimity, the public has acquiesced to the narrative that the slowdown in 1Q 2014 annualized growth rates have been an aberration as explained above.

Unfortunately for popular wisdom, there is a possible non-economic, but financial-statistical force lurking behind the shadows. This is called the regression/reversion to the mean.

Mean reversion is a theory suggesting that prices and returns eventually move back towards the mean or average[25]


image

The above represents the Philippine annual GDP based on different frames.

It’s a sad reality that the public will not set aside their blinders from their impassioned belief of the perpetuity of this bogus boom, so no matter the facts or the theory they will just disregard anything that goes against their deeply held belief.

Nevertheless from an objective perspective, even by just looking at mere statistical figures, one would come to realize that the economic growth rate decline of 1Q 2014 represents the following:

1) It’s NOT an aberration or anomaly. From the peak growth at 7.9% in the 2nd quarter of 2013, the recent slowdown signifies the THIRD quarter of decline (topmost chart). Simply put, there were other two growth rate retracements ahead of this quarter.

2) The reaction has been SENSATIONALIST. Here are the growth rates during the past 4 quarters in percent: 7.9 (2q13), 7.0 (3q13), 6.3 (4q13) and 5.7 (1q14). The differentials seen by quarters: -.9% (3q-2q), -.7% (4q-3q) and -.6% (1q14-4q13). The rate of decline during this quarter (-.6%) hasn’t even been as significant as the initial drop a quarter past the apogee (-.9%). Yet the ferocity of denial

3) This time IS NOT different. Recent events back this up. In 2010, the statistical economy’s annualized growth rate jumped to a stunning high of 8.9%, before falling back to 3 to 4% until 1q of 2012 (middle window)

4) The slowdown looks MOST likely a REVERSION to the MEAN.

Tradingeconomics.com says that the average growth rate of the Philippine economy from 2001 until 2014 has been at 5.04%.

Outside the 2013 7.9% growth, there have been three times during the past 13 years where statistical economic growth reached 7% and beyond, yet all three failed to sustain their ‘peak’ levels. The current trend looks like history replaying itself. (lowest pane)

Here is a short chronicle.

In 2004, 7% growth rates were posted in two consecutive quarters, particularly 7.1% (2q) and 7.2% (3q), but the growth rates receded back to 4.5-5.5% through 2006. By the same token in 2007, the economy’s growth rates picked up and reaccelerated. Growth rates zoomed past 6%, and climaxed at 8.3% (2q). But law of mean reversion flexed its muscles. Growth rates went downhill and nearly fell into a negative zone during the last 3 quarters of 2009, specifically 1% (2q), 1.6% (3q) and .5% (4q).

The above figures reveal of slightly nuanced perspectives offered by different time frames but they end up with a similar conclusion: The 7-8% growth rates are UNLIKELY a NEW Normal but outliers subject to the reversion to the mean.

Notice that I strictly focused on numbers without interjecting economic-political extrapolations.

Now for the economic context: The downturn of 2008-9 has been in response to the US epicenter induced global financial crisis. The BSP has used this global crisis as justification for the grand pirouette towards a bubble economy via aggregate demand-quasi permanent boom policies. The declines from the 2010’s highs hardly emanated from external factors (even when the Euro Crisis emerged).

The recent 3 successive quarters of slackening from post 2013 highs, ironically emerged alongside the 30+% money supply growth rates. This means that exploding growth rates of debt which has been ventilated through money supply growth rates, has been producing less and less of economic output—diminishing returns of debt (again as discussed above)

If the laws of the regression/reversion to the mean will be followed (even without economic interpolation) then statistical economic growth will most likely surprise the mainstream NEGATIVELY as economic growth are south bound in the coming one or two years, with probable interim bounces.

Another way to look at this is if history does rhyme, then it means a big, big, big disappointment for the consensus bearing exceptionally high expectations.

Oh yes, the inflation (stagflation) story alone represents a huge headwind to real economic growth. Compounded with a bubble cycle, these twin lethal forces would fluidly dovetail with the reversion to the mean.

One of the saddest lessons of history is this: If we’ve been bamboozled long enough, we tend to reject any evidence of the bamboozle. We’re no longer interested in finding out the truth. The bamboozle has captured us. It’s simply too painful to acknowledge, even to ourselves, that we’ve been taken. Once you give a charlatan power over you, you almost never get it back. - Carl Sagan

Bingo! BPO Growth Rates Tumbles Big

In questioning the sustainability of the shopping mall boom, last year I opined that one sunrise area, the BPO industry, will hardly sustain its robust growth trend enough to support consumer demand.

I wrote[26], (bold mine)
Nevertheless, where I believe they gone astray is that they have ignored the S-Curve cycle of the technology industry..

In short, unless there will be assimilation of more productivity through newer innovation, the industry’s growth diffusion levels, as it ages, is bound to slowdown. I have used this curve to rightly predict the slowdown in telecom penetration levels.
The BSP notes of a substantial decline in the growth rate of the BPO industry[27] (bole mine): The country’s IT-BPO services industry remained robust in 2012, as shown by the results of the Survey of Information Technology-Business Process Outsourcing (IT-BPO) Services conducted by the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP). Revenues from the industry continued to register double-digit growth during the year, albeit at a decelerated rate of 11.4 percent compared to the 20.1 percent posted in 2011. Total revenues of the industry rose to US$13.5 billion in 2012 from US$12.1 billion in the previous year.

Bingo again! 

IF the declining growth rates in the BPO sector will be sustained, then this will not just affect the consumer demand, more importantly, this will slam hardest the vertical ‘office’ real estate industry.

Many aggressive capex of vertical real estate projects have banked on the BPO’s astronomical sustained rate of growth. Yet as growth slows, so will demand. Unfortunately many projects have already been committed based on such Pollyannaish expectations.

Massive miscalculation expressed as malinvestments translates to coming massive losses.

Phisix: More Marking the Close, Manic Punts Amidst Slowing Volume

As I have been saying, the convictions of a one way trade have been so strong in such a way that any profit taking will be seen as buying opportunities. In other words, retracements appear as political incorrect and impermissible.

The excessively overvalued and technically overbought Phisix came close to neutralizing last week’s 2.4% decline with this week’s 1.73% leap.


image

Of course, part of this week’s gains has been attained by the massaging of the Phisix benchmark index levels.

This is a minor incident anyway, but it shows how desperate the bulls have become in employing price fixing measures which seems to have become a regular fixture.

Last Thursday, the Phisix (left window, chart from colfinancial.com) spent most of the day in the red, down by about .2+%. Well that was until the last minute where Phisix closed unchanged. Much of the last minute counterbalancing push has been via the Holding sector (right). The financials and industrials participated too (not in chart) but not as much as the star of the day, the holding sector.

image

One of the most interesting developments has been the unfolding manic sentiment conspicuously seen in the Philippine Stock Exchange’s market internals.

Daily number of trades (averaged weekly, left window) has declined during last weeks’ profit taking but not enough to go below the May 2013 levels where the Phisix traded at the record highs of 7,400. This week’s rebound has apparently rekindled the feverish speculator’s sentiments where second and third tier issues has been bidded up along with Phisix heavyweights

Nonetheless the rebound in the Phisix comes with declining volume (based on the average weekly peso volume/average weekly number of trades). In short, bullish conviction has been strong alright, but the strength of which has been directed on mostly smaller and illiquid issues.

But the bullish backdrop on the general market has hardly been strong enough to be backed by volume. Instead, the declining Peso per trade volume suggests of weakening foundations for the current run-up.

The ECB Takes the ‘Euthanasia of the Rentier’ to Reality

It’s an extreme curiosity to see how the average citizens of the world have been treated by central bankers as some kind of guinea pigs subject to their social engineering experiments. These unelected bureaucrats seem to have little qualms on their experiments because they bear little cost on them. In short, these bureaucrats have little skin on the game. And the burden or price from such failures will be carried by the hapless guinea pigs, us, through debt/currency crisis from boom bust cycles and through inflation.

Yet unfortunately, what they have been dabbling with has repeatedly tried by political authorities which have resulted to generally similar outcomes, since eons ago. The difference is that the earlier forms of money debasement have been more primitive through ‘coin clipping’ rather than today’s digitally based central banking money standard of ‘credit easing’ policies aimed at manipulating the yield curves, portfolio balancing and the doctrine of smart central bankers protecting the economy from the nasty side effects of a stock market crash.

Even the variations of credit easing policies tried and tested by various developed economies have hardly brought any real economic recovery back to the forefront. And this is why governments via central banks have increasingly been pushing monetary experiments to its limits.

What this has instead produced has been a massive redistribution or transfer of wealth from the currency holders to asset owners or what we may call as reverse Robin Hood. Importantly what all these have racked up has been a massive asset bubbles and unsustainable debt all over the world.

The Wall Streets of the World, particularly in the developed economies wildly cheered and celebrated the latest aggressive move by the European Central Bank’s Mario Draghi to drive down bank deposit rates into negative territory combined with a 4 year Targeted Long Term Refinancing Operations (TLTRO) and a prospective asset purchasing foray on Asset Backed Securities[28], thus according to the mainstream the ushering in of a “new era of negative interest rates”.

This in essence would mark a dream a come true or the realization of the “euthanasia of rentier” as advocated by chief inflation proponent John Maynard Keynes[29].

Yet instead of practical men…who are usually slaves of some defunct economist as Mr. Keynes once remarked, ECB’s Mario Draghi seems to have perfected what Mr. Keynes says of slaves of some defunct economist but not as a practical man but as “madmen in authority”.

The Negative Deposit Rates is said “to apply to reserve holding in excess of the minimum reserve requirements”[30].

Banks hold reserves in order to ensure payment to depositors on demand. By penalizing banks for keeping reserves with the central banks, in effect, banks will now be forced to reduce reserves and to indulge in greater risks of impairing their balance sheets by either issuing risky loans or by wantonly engaging in more asset speculations.

image

In addition, the ECB’s response to supposedly a low-flation problem has been to force banks into lending even when the recent crisis has ballooned rather than caused a de-leveraging in her banking system. The Eurozone’s public and private debt relative to the GDP has inflated to 462.6% in 2013 from 413.9% in 2008 (left window)

Despite the magical effect of Draghi’s “do whatever it takes to save the euro” of reviving the convergence trade in Europe’s periphery bonds, there has been little recovery in bank lending activities and even in the real economy.

The Keynesian authorities and their followers fail to see that this has been a balance sheet problem. Euro banks hesitate to lend because of still impaired assets due to the previous days of reckless lending and due to the lack of creditworthiness of borrowers. Euro banks know that their balance sheets have been artificially propped up by money printing by global central banks. On the other hand, companies in Europe’s periphery hardly invest because of poor prospects of investment returns and or that they already have borne heavy yokes of debt. Meanwhile households of the Eurozone has exhausted on their borrowing capacity. So overleverage has been the problem and remains the problem for the Eurozone.

The ECB’s actions extrapolate to even more striking imbalances ahead. As fund manager and analyst Doug Noland of the Credit Bubble Bulletin observed[31], (bold mine)
The markets foresee only more central bank liquidity making its way to enticing market Bubbles. Italian 10-year sovereign yields sank 20 bps points this week to a record low 2.76%. Imagine a country with complete economic stagnation and debt-to-GDP approaching 130% - and borrowing at yields below 3%. This week saw Spain’s yields sink another 22 bps to a record low 2.63%. Portuguese yields sank 11 bps to a near-record low 3.52%. With mounting debt and deep economic problems, French yields ended the week at 1.70%. A strong case can be made that the European debt Bubble has inflated into one of history’s greatest mispricings of debt securities. European bonds – and global risk markets more generally – are showing signs of upside dislocation – likely spurred by derivatives and speculative trades gone haywire. The “global government finance Bubble” thesis finds added confirmation on a weekly basis.
I would add carry trades to this[32], especially with the ECB’s recent action.

In sum, the ECB has been attempting to solve her debt problems by gorging on even more debt. As I have repeatedly analogized, this would be similar to solving drug dependence or addiction with even MORE drugs!

Yet it’s no guarantee that forcing money out of the banking system will find their way into spending via credit expansion. And this is why experts like Kenneth Rogoff have recently suggested for governments to embrace a cashless society[33] in the fear that people may hoard cash instead. Experts would like governments to grab outright control of everyone’s money!

While the ECB’s new era of easing may propel asset markets like stocks higher over the interim, the alternative is that this may abet propagating “inflation” on a global scale.

Yet given severely overvalued and overstretched asset markets, I am doubtful if these central bank induced boom can last.

And global price inflation rates have already been picking up for most of the world including the US (see right pane, chart from SNBCHF).

In the Eurozone, German and French inflation has been little changed from 2013. It’s only in the crisis afflicted peripheries where low-flation has been apparent.

Again should consumer price inflation continue to accelerate, this will be incompatible with the sustainability of debt financed asset bubble boom.

Moreover, given the simmering inflation and debt problems in Asia, I certainly am in doubt if they can join the US-ECB asset market shindig for long.

Even Malaysia’s hybrid national sovereign fund and private investment vehicle, the 1Malaysia Development Berhad (1MDB) has more than just debt problems where cash flow from her generic businesses can only finance 53% of interest payments, so 1MDB has basically embraced what Hyman Minsky has warned as Ponzi financing or DEBT IN DEBT OUT[34].

As you can see wherever you glance there are more problems or risks than opportunities presented.

Bottom line: negative deposit rates means that we should brace for a global crisis in a not so distant future.
Human beings have a natural tendency to ignore obvious warning signs and take the path of least resistance. It’s a much simpler prospect to stick our heads in the sand than to acknowledge uncomfortable truths and risks.—Simon Black







[4] Oryza.com May 2014 Rice Market Review June 4, 2014

[5] Gerado P. Sicat Rice smuggling, corruption, protectionism – almost the same thing! Philstar.com February 5, 2014

[6] V. BRUCE J. TOLENTINO The Price of Rice Protectionism Wall Street Journal Asia April 14, 2008

[7] President Benigno S. Aquino III 2013 Budget Message of President Aquino Gov.ph

[8] Manila Standard Today, DOJ memo on rice import withheld February 26, 2014

[9] Yahoo.com NFA: Rice supply sufficient December 4, 2013

[10] BusinessMirror.com PHL Asia’s fastest rice producer–DA May 4, 2014

[11] Inquirer.net PH rice imports to hit 1.2M tons in 2014 April 14, 2014

[12] Normalyn Yap TIBAO Why Does the Philippines Import Rice: A Solution to the Rice Shortage, National Chung Hsing University Taiwan




[16] Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas Inflation Increases Further to 4.5 Percent in May June 5, 2014

[17] Department of Trade and Industry The Price Act of July 1992 REPUBLIC ACT NO. 7581 AN ACT PROVIDING PROTECTION TO CONSUMERS BY STABILIZING THE PRICES OF BASIC NECESSITIES AND PRIME COMMODITIES AND BY PRESCRIBING MEASURES AGAINST UNDUE PRICE INCREASES DURING EMERGENCY SITUATIONS AND LIKE OCCASIONS…Price ACT…1. DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE (A) Basic Necessities • rice • corn • cooking oil • fresh, dried fish and other marine products • fresh eggs • fresh pork, beef and poultry meat • fresh milk • fresh vegetables • root crops • sugar

[18] Rappler.com Rent control extended for two years December 18, 2013


[20] Diwa C Guinigundo Measurement of inflation and the Philippine monetary policy framework Bank of International Settlements




[24] Wall Street Journal Blog, loc cit

[25] Investopedia.com Mean Reversion





[30] Danske Bank Research Implications of the ECB easing measures, June 6, 2014

[31] Doug Noland Credit Allocation, Credit Bubble Bulletin June 6, 2014 PrudentBear.com